www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 1
I
n Iraq and Afghanistan, the use of contractors has reached a level unprece-
dented in U.S. military operations. As of March 31, 2010, the United States
deployed 175,000 troops and 207,000 contractors in the war zones. Con-
tractors represented 50 percent of the Department of Defense (DOD) work-
force in Iraq and 59 percent in Afghanistan.
1
ese numbers include both armed
and unarmed contractors. us, for the purposes of this paper, the term contrac-
tor includes both armed and unarmed personnel unless otherwise specied. e
presence of contractors on the battleeld is obviously not a new phenomenon
but has dramatically increased from the ratio of 1 contractor to 55 military per-
sonnel in Vietnam to 1:1 in Iraq
2
and 1.43:1 in Afghanistan.
3
is increase is the logical outcome of a series of decisions going back de-
cades. Force structure reductions—ranging from the post-Vietnam decisions that
moved most Army logistics support elements to the Army Reserve and Guard
4
to the post–Cold War reduction that cut the Army from 18 to 10 divisions with
corresponding cuts in support forces—greatly reduced the Services’ ability to sup-
port long-term operations. Next, a series of decisions in the 1990s led to the em-
ployment of contractors in the Balkans for tasks ranging from traditional camp-
building to the new concept of “force development that saw contractor MPRI
training the Croatian army. Finally, the decision to invade Iraq with minimum
forces left the United States with too few troops in-theater to deal with the disor-
der that resulted from the removal of Saddam Hussein. us, it is understandable
that the immediate, unanticipated need for large numbers of logistics and security
personnel, the shortage of such troops on active duty, and the precedent for using
Private Contractors
in Conict Zones:
The Good, the Bad, and
the Strategic Impact
by T.X. Hammes
Strategic Forum
National Defense University
CENTER FOR STRATEGIC RESEARCH
About the Author
Dr. T.X. Hammes, a retired U.S. Marine
Corps ofcer, is a Senior Research
Fellow in the Center for Strategic
Research, Institute for National
Strategic Studies, at the National
Defense University. Comments and
questions may be directed to thomas.
Key Points
The United States has hired record
numbers of contractors to serve
in the conict zones of Iraq and
Afghanistan but has not seriously
examined their strategic impact.
There are clearly advantages to
using contractors in conict zones,
but they have three inherent
characteristics that have serious
negative effects during counterin-
surgency operations. We cannot
effectively control the quality of
the contractors or control their
actions, but the population holds
us responsible for everything the
contractors do, or fail to do.
Contractors compete with the
host government for a limited
pool of qualied personnel and
dramatically change local
power structures.
Contractors reduce the political
capital necessary to commit U.S.
forces to war, impact the legitima-
cy of a counterinsurgency effort,
and reduce its perceived morality.
These factors attack our nation’s
critical vulnerability in an irregu-
lar war—the political will of the
American people.
November 2010
2 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
contractors in the Balkans caused the Pentagon to turn to
contractors to ll the immediate operational needs. How-
ever, the subsequent failure to conduct a careful analysis
of the wisdom of using contractors is less understandable.
e executive branch has conducted numerous investiga-
tions into fraud, waste, and corruption in the contracting
process. Congress has held hearings and established the
Commission on Wartime Contracting in Iraq and Af-
ghanistan. Yet the U.S. Government has not systematically
explored the essential question: Does using contractors in
a conict zone make strategic sense?
is paper explores that question. It examines the
good, the bad, and the strategic impact of using contractors
in conict zones. It concludes with policy recommenda-
tions for the future employment of contractors and outlines
additional actions needed to understand and cope with the
rapidly expanding use of armed contractors worldwide.
The Good
Contractors provide a number of advantages over
military personnel or civil servants—speed of deploy-
ment, continuity, reduction of troop requirements, re-
duction of military casualties, economic inputs to local
economies, and, in some cases, executing tasks the mili-
tary and civilian workforce simply cannot. is section
examines each of these advantages in turn.
Speed of deployment—the ability to quickly mo-
bilize and deploy large numbers of personnel—is par-
ticularly important when a plan fails to anticipate prob-
lems. Since the Pentagon had not planned to keep large
numbers of troops in Afghanistan or Iraq for any period
of time, it had not planned for the required logistics
support. e Pentagon also failed to anticipate the re-
there has been little investigation
by the U.S. Government into the
strategic impact of contractors in
conict zones
quirement for large numbers of security personnel to
protect all U.S. activities (including political and recon-
struction activities) once the Afghan and Iraqi govern-
ments were toppled.
By tapping into databases, running job fairs in the
United States, and contracting for labor from ird World
companies, contractors were able to quickly recruit, process,
and ship personnel to run base camps, drive trucks, and
perform the hundreds of housekeeping chores required to
maintain both combat forces and civil administrators spread
across Iraq and Afghanistan. More challenging was nd-
ing qualied personnel to provide security for the rapidly
growing U.S. presence in both nations. Private companies
managed to nd people, hire them, and move them into
the country—all without the political problems inherent
in mobilizing additional U.S. military forces to execute the
same tasks. e combination of speed and a low political
prole made contractors an attractive choice to provide the
resources for which the administration had failed to plan. In
addition, the use of contractors aligned with previous de-
cisions and the administrations faith in the eciency and
eectiveness of private business compared to governmental
organization. Both inside and outside Iraq and Afghani-
stan, contractors replaced the tens of thousands of soldiers
normally required to move, stage, marshal, and transport
personnel and supplies into conict zones.
5
Continuity is a second major advantage of contrac-
tors. While the U.S. military has a policy that ensures the
vast majority of personnel rotate every 6 to 12 months,
contractors are often willing to stay for longer periods.
For key billets, companies can oer signicant bonuses to
personnel who stay. e companies know that they will
reap commensurate savings due to the personnel conti-
nuity, and employees see an opportunity for signicantly
increased pay. Sometimes, moreover, longevity leads to a
greater understanding of the situation. is can lead to
more eective decisionmaking to include an understand-
ing of the political impact of the contractor’s decisions.
e most highly prized attribute of private contrac-
tors is that they reduce troop requirements by replacing
military personnel. is reduces the military and political
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 3
resources that must be dedicated to the war. At the height
of the surge in April 2008, DOD stated it had 163,900
contractors supporting 160,000 troops in Iraq.
6
With-
out the presence of contractors, the United States would
have had to provide literally twice as many troops. e
U.S. Armed Forces struggled to maintain 160,000 troops
in Iraq; it is doubtful that they could have supported the
320,000 needed if contractors were not employed. While
the vast majority of contractor personnel were involved in
noncombatant logistics tasks, DOD estimated there were
over 20,000 armed contractors in Iraq during 2007. Other
organizations have much higher estimates.
7
Even using
the Pentagons lower estimate, contractors provided three
times more armed troops than the British. It should also
be noted that in Iraq and Afghanistan, many unarmed,
logistic support personnel functioned in what the military
would dene as a combat role. e drivers were subjected
to both improvised explosive devices and direct re attacks.
is combination of drivers willing to run the gauntlet of
ambushes and armed contractors replaced at least two full
combat divisions. Given the very low support-to-operator
ratio that contractors maintain, it is not unreasonable to
estimate they actually replaced three divisions.
e contractors not only provided relief in terms of
personnel tempo but also reduced military casualties. Con-
tractors absorbed over 25 percent of the killed in action
in Iraq, which reduced the political resources required to
maintain support for the conict. By the end of 2009, con-
tractors reported almost 1,800 dead and 40,000 wounded in
Iraq and Afghanistan.
8
As the ghting in Afghanistan gets
worse, contractors are now suering more deaths than U.S.
forces: “In the rst two quarters of 2010 alone, contractor
deaths represented more than half—53 percent—of all fa-
talities. is point bears emphasis: since January 2010, more
contractors have died in Iraq and Afghanistan than U.S.
military soldiers.”
9
For practical purposes, these casualties
were o the books” in that they had no real impact on the
political discussions about the war. As Peter Singer noted:
ere was no outcry whenever contractors were called
up and deployed, or even killed. If the gradual death
use of contractors aligned with
the administration’s faith in
private business compared to
governmental organization
toll among American troops threatened to slowly
wear down public support, contractor casualties
were not counted in ocial death tolls and had no
impact on these ratings. . . . ese gures mean that
the private military industry has suered more losses
in Iraq than the rest of the coalition of allied nations
combined. e losses are also far more than any single
U.S. Army division has experienced.
10
Contractor casualties are not reported via the Pen-
tagon, but only through the U.S. Department of Labor.
Its Web site notes that these are not comprehensive sta-
tistics but only represent those injuries and deaths that
resulted in insurance claims.
11
us, it is dicult if not
impossible to determine how many additional casualties
were suered by other nations’ contractors in either Iraq
or Afghanistan.
Replacing these contractors, both armed and
unarmed, would have required additional major
mobilizations of Reserves or a dramatic increase
in Army and Marine Corps end-strength. In eect,
the mobilization of civilian contractors allowed the
United States to engage in a protracted conict in
Iraq without convincing the U.S. public of the need
for additional major mobilizations or major increases
in the Active Armed Forces. e decision to hire
contractors can be taken out of view of the public
while decisions to increase troop strength are usually
subject to intense debate. Opponents of contractors
point out that this makes it easier for U.S. political
leaders to commit forces to protracted conicts
precisely because it reduces uniformed casualties.
12
Whether the tendency of contractors to reduce the
4 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
political cost of operations is a good thing depends
upon one’s view of the particular conict.
Another advantage frequently cited by proponents of
the use of contractors is that of cost. According to their
calculations, contractors are much cheaper to use than gov-
ernment employees. In fact, the actual costs remain a point
of contention. e Congressional Research Service report-
ed that the relative cost advantage of the contractors can
vary, and may diminish or disappear altogether, depend-
ing on the circumstances and contract.”
13
Determining
actual costs is extremely dicult due to the large number
of variables involved—some of them currently impossible
to document. For instance, with over 40,000 U.S. contrac-
tors wounded to date, we are unable to estimate potential
long-term care costs to the U.S. Government. While con-
tractors may claim their insurance covers those costs, the
government, in fact, paid for that insurance through the
contract, and if the coverage proves insucient, the gov-
ernment may well end up paying for the continued care
through various governmental medical programs. In short,
long-term costs associated with employing contractors in a
conict environment are essentially unknowable.
However, one cost benet of contractors is indis-
putable. As soon as the need goes away, they can be let
go when the contract expires. us, unlike military or
government employees who continue on the payroll or
return to Reserve status, contractors are simply paid o
and sent home.
Another useful aspect of contracting is that it can
provide economic inputs to local economies by hiring
locals to provide services. Creating jobs and stimulat-
ing the economy are key aspects of population-centric
counterinsurgency. In the Balkans and Afghanistan,
the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) and
International Security Assistance Force (ISAF) have
hired large numbers of local personnel to conduct both
armed and unarmed tasks. Carefully targeted contracts
can be used to co-opt local power structures to support
the government.
General David Petraeus, ISAF commander,
specically tasked his commanders to be aware of
both the benets and dangers of contracting in
Afghanistan. He ordered them to monitor their
contracts carefully to ensure they are contributing to
the counterinsurgency campaign.
14
A nal, critical advantage is that contractors can
execute tasks that U.S. military and civilian forces sim-
ply cannot. Some tasks, such as providing large numbers
of interpreters, are obvious and widely applicable. Oth-
ers are situation-specic. For instance, in Afghanistan,
we lack the forces to secure our primary supply lines
to Pakistan because they run through areas controlled
or heavily contested by either the Taliban or bandits
and police who charge for use of the road. Further-
more, if history is any guide, even a heavy presence of
U.S. troops would not guarantee the delivery of sup-
plies. Fortunately, Afghan contractors display the mix
of force, personal connections, and negotiation skills to
maintain our supply lines.
The Bad
When serving within conict zones, particularly
during a counterinsurgency, contractors create a number
of signicant problems from tactical to strategic levels.
ree inherent characteristics of contractors create prob-
lems for the government. First, the government does not
control the quality of the personnel that the contractor
hires. Second, unless it provides a government ocer or
noncommissioned ocer for each construction project,
convoy, personal security detail, or facilities-protection
unit, the government does not control, or even know
about, contractors’ daily interactions with the local popu-
lation. Finally, the population holds the government re-
sponsible for everything that the contractors do or fail
to do. Since insurgency is essentially a competition for
the mobilization of civilian
contractors allowed the
United States to engage in a
protracted conict in Iraq
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 5
legitimacy between the government and insurgents, this
factor elevates the issue of quality and tactical control to
the strategic level. In addition to these inherent char-
acteristics, there are numerous other negative outcomes
that ow from using contractors. Contractors compete
directly with the host nation for a limited pool of edu-
cated, trained personnel. eir presence and actions can
dramatically change local power structures. ey frag-
ment the chain of command. And when they fail to per-
form, contractors can be dicult to re.
Quality control is a well-publicized issue. Repeated
reports of substandard construction, fraud, and theft
highlight the problems associated with unarmed con-
tractors. As noted above, these incidents are being in-
vestigated. In addition, the U.S. Government is working
hard to rene contracting and oversight procedures to
reduce these types of problems. Despite their best ef-
forts, however, contracting ocers cannot control how
contractors treat their local employees. Poor treatment,
lack of respect for local customs, skills, and methods—
and even physical abuse to include sexual exploitation—
have been recurrent problems with unarmed contractors.
Unfortunately, the problem is just as prevalent with
armed contractors. While high-end personal security
details generally are well trained, less visible armed con-
tractors display less quality. When suicide bombers be-
gan striking Iraqi armed forces recruiting stations, the
contractor responsible for recruiting the Iraqi forces sub-
contracted for a security force. e contractor was prom-
ised former Gurkhas. What showed up in Iraq a couple
of weeks later were untrained, underequipped Nepalese
villagers.
15
Not only did these contractors provide inad-
equate security, the United States armed them and au-
thorized them to use deadly force in its name.
Since the government neither recruits nor trains in-
dividual armed contractors, it essentially has to trust the
contractor to provide quality personnel. In this case, the
subcontractor took shortcuts despite the obvious risk to
the personnel manning the recruiting stations. Even if
the government hires enough contracting ocers, how
can it determine the combat qualications of individuals
and teams of armed personnel? e U.S. military dedi-
cates large facilities, major exercises, expensive simula-
tions, and combat-experienced stas to determine if U.S.
units are properly trained. Contractors do not. We need
to acknowledge that contracting ocers have no truly
eective control over the quality of the personnel the
contractors hire. e quality control problems are greatly
exacerbated when the contractor uses subcontractors to
provide services. ese personnel are at least one layer
removed from the contracting ocer and thus subject to
even less scrutiny.
In reality, it is virtually impossible to determine the
actual eectiveness of any contractors—armed or un-
armed—until they begin to operate in theater (and only
then if a member of the U.S. Government can observe
the contractors as they operate).
Compounding the problems created by lack of qual-
ity control, the government does not control the contrac-
tors’ daily contact with the population. Despite continued
eorts to increase government oversight of contractor
operations, nothing short of having sucient numbers
of qualied U.S. Government personnel accompanying
and commanding contractors will provide control. is
lack of control usually means we may get poorly wired
buildings, malfunctioning computer systems, and unn-
ished projects. However, too often, it includes incidents
of bullying, abuse, intimidation, and even killing of local
civilians such as the DynCorp employee who ran a child
sex ring in the Balkans or the September 2007 Blackwa-
ter shootings in Nisour Square, Baghdad.
is lack of quality and tactical control greatly
increases the impact of the third major problem: the
United States is held responsible for everything the
contractors do or fail to do. Despite the fact the United
contractors can execute tasks
that U.S. military and civilian
forces simply cannot
6 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
States has no eective quality or operational control
over the contractors, the local population rightly holds
it responsible for all contractor failures. Numerous
personal conversations with Iraqis revealed a deep dis-
gust with the failure of many contractors to provide
promised services despite being well paid. ere was
even more anger with the actions of armed contrac-
tors. Iraqis noted the United States gave the armed
contractors authority to use deadly force in its name.
While Iraqis were not condent that American forc-
es would be punished for killing Iraqis, they believed
it was at least a possibility. However, the Iraqis were
convinced that contractors were simply above any
law. e Iraqi perception that it will be impossible to
prosecute a contractor is reected in a Congressional
Research Service report that required 17 pages simply
to outline the various legal structures under which a
contractor might be prosecuted. e paper indicated
that there was no clear legal precedent for prosecuting
contractors, and it noted none had been prosecuted up
through August 2008.
16
ese perceptions can seriously undercut the legiti-
macy of both the host nation and U. S. Government. A
key measure of the legitimacy of a government is a mo-
nopoly on the use of force within its boundaries. e very
act of hiring armed contractors dilutes that monopoly.
17
Legitimate governments are also responsible for the ac-
tions of their agents—particularly those actions taken
against their own populations. Despite eorts to increase
the accountability of contractors, the Congressional Re-
search Service noted the widespread perception that con-
tractors who commit crimes against host nation people are
outside the legal reach of both the host country and the
United States.
18
Contractors, armed or unarmed, could be
quickly own out of the country if their company believed
they violated a law. And while the United States has laws
criminalizing certain activities, the cost and diculty of
trying a contractor for crimes that occurred overseas in a
conict zone have so far deterred U.S. prosecutors. In over
7 years of activity in Iraq, no contractor has been convicted
in a U.S. court of a crime against Iraqi citizens.
Exacerbating the legitimacy issue, contractors of all
kinds are a serious irritant to the host nation population.
Armed contractors irritate because they are an unac-
countable group that can and does impose its will upon
the population in many daily encounters: forcing locals
o the road, using the wrong side of the road, and point-
ing weapons at civilians. Even unarmed contractors irri-
tate the population when they take relatively well-paying
jobs that local people desperately need while at the same
time driving up prices. Contractors, when they do hire
locals, often treat them with a lack of respect and trust.
Furthermore, the complete control over who works on
projects combined with the disrespect shown those locals
that are hired reinforces local perceptions of the United
States as an occupying power.
In addition to undercutting government legitimacy,
the use of contractors may actually undercut local gov-
ernment power. In Afghanistan, security and reconstruc-
tion contracts have resulted in signicant shifts in relative
power between competing Afghan qawms
19
as well as al-
legations of corruption. Dexter Filkins, writing in the New
York Times, notes that the power structure in Orugzan
Province, Afghanistan, has changed completely due to the
U.S. Governments selecting Matiullah Khan to provide
security for convoys from Kandahar to Tirin Kot:
With his NATO millions, and the American
backing, Mr. Matiullah has grown into the
strongest political and economic force in the region.
He estimates that his salaries support 15,000 people
in this impoverished province. . . . is has irritated
some local leaders, who say that the line between Mr.
Matiullahs business interest and the government
it is virtually impossible to
determine the effectiveness of any
contractors until they begin to
operate in theater
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 7
has disappeared. . . . Both General [Nick] Carter
[commander of ISAF South] and Hanif Atmar,
the Afghan interior minister, said they hoped to
disband Mr. Matiullahs militia soon—or at least
to bring it under formal government control. . . .
General Carter said that while he had no direct
proof in Mr. Matiullahs case, he harbored more
general worries that the legions of unregulated
Afghan security companies had a nancial interest
in prolonging chaos.
20
us, an unacknowledged but serious strategic im-
pact of using contractors is to directly undercut both the
legitimacy and the authority of the host nation govern-
ment. In this case, the shortage of ISAF troops and sheer
diculty of maintaining security along this route mean
that there is currently no feasible alternative. at makes
it more important than ever that the U.S. Government
takes specic actions to minimize the negative strategic
impacts of this operational necessity. Contracting actions
must be seen as an integral part of the campaign rather
than simply treated as a logistics function.
Contracting also has a direct and measureable im-
pact on the local economy. When the U.S. Government
passes its authority to a prime contractor, that contractor
then controls a major source of new wealth and power in
the community. However, the contractor is motivated by
two factors: maximizing prot and making operations run
smoothly. is means that even if he devotes resources to
understanding the impact of his operations on society, his
decisions on how to allocate those resources will dier
from those of someone trying to govern the area. For in-
stance, various contractors’ policies of hiring South Asians
rather than Iraqis angered Iraqis during the critical early
phases of the insurgency. Desperate for jobs, the Iraqis saw
third country nationals getting jobs that Iraqis were both
qualied for and eager to do.
21
While there were clear
business and security reasons for doing so, the decision
was a slap in the face of Iraqis at a time of record un-
employment. In Afghanistan, the contractor can literally
shift the local power structure by picking one qwam over
another to execute the contract. e winning qwam gains
rich resources and access to both U.S. and Afghan ocials.
In contrast, the U.S. Government in the form of a
Provincial Reconstruction Team (PRT) commander or a
unit commander writes contracts specically to inuence
the political and security situation in the area. Com-
manders see the contracts themselves as a campaign tool.
While such contracts are limited by the cultural under-
standing of the commander and are often less ecient
for the specic project, this system can be much more
eective in the overall counterinsurgency campaign.
A related problem is the perception of the local
population concerning how these contracts are managed.
In Afghanistan, many Afghans are convinced that some
contracts expend up to 80 percent of the funds on man-
agement. e Agency Coordinating Body for Afghan
Relief states that 40 percent of nonmilitary aid goes
straight to corporate prot and salaries. Prot margins
run as high as 50 percent, and full-time expatriate con-
sultants cost between $250,000 and $350,000 per year.
22
Many of the contracts run through multiple subcontract-
ing companies before the aid reaches the Afghan people;
each subcontractor takes a percentage for administrative
overhead.
23
ese conrmed cases of misuse of develop-
ment funds further reduce the weak legitimacy of the
Afghan government as well as ISAF eorts.
ere are also a number of indirect consequences of
employing armed contractors. First, this practice opens the
door for local organizations to build militias under the cover
of being a security company. It is dicult to object to other
elements of a society hiring security when the government
is doing so. is is particularly true when the government is
hiring both locals and foreign nationals to provide security.
even unarmed contractors irritate
the population when they take jobs
that local people need while at the
same time driving up prices
8 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
If the government needs private contractors to feel safe, the
citizens, local businesses, or even local political organiza-
tions can certainly argue that they do, too. is fact has cre-
ated signicant problems for ISAF in Afghanistan:
Because PSCs [private security companies] are
under the control of powerful individuals, rather
than the Afghan National Security Forces, they
compete with state security forces and interfere
with a government monopoly on the use of force.
ere is growing pressure from ISAF and within
the Afghan government to reform and regulate
these companies. Major General Nick Carter, the
commander of Regional Command–South, recently
briefed that ISAF was developing a strategy to
regulate PSCs as part of the Kandahar Operations
unfolding in summer 2010.
24
In addition, private security companies can com-
pete directly with host nation attempts to recruit and
retain military and police personnel. In January 2010,
Major General Michael Ward, Deputy Commander Po-
lice, NATO Training Mission Afghanistan, stated that
Afghanistans government was considering capping
the pay of private security rms because Afghan po-
lice were deserting in large numbers for the better pay
and working conditions associated with private compa-
nies.
25
is has created signicant problems for ISAF.
General Carter told reporters:
[P]rivate security companies and militias are a
serious problem. . . . this is, of course, something that
is of our own creation to a degree . . . where we
contracted out everything to the civilian market,
has created these private security companies.
And of course they are paid a great deal more
than our Afghan security forces, which in itself is
counterproductive because, of course, the temptation
for a soldier in the ANP [Afghan National Police]
is to go across to a private security company because
he might earn double in pay.
26
Contract hiring of unarmed personnel also com-
petes directly with the host nation civil government. In
both Iraq and Afghanistan, educated professionals took
jobs as drivers or clerks with contractors and nongovern-
mental organizations (NGOs) simply because the jobs
paid more than they could earn working for their own
governments. In eect, ISAF and NGO hiring has creat-
ed an internal “brain drain.” is is of particular concern
in Afghanistan where human capital is a major limita-
tion on the ability of the government to function.
On August 16, 2010, President Hamid Karzai de-
creed that all private security contractors must cease
operations in Afghanistan within 4 months.
27
Unfor-
tunately, currently ISAF and most humanitarian agen-
cies rely on armed contractors to provide security for
essential operations, and neither ISAF nor the Afghan
Security Forces is prepared to execute those missions.
At the time of this writing, it is too early to evaluate
the impact of President Karzai’s announcement, but it
does highlight the political complications that such con-
tractors inject into counterinsurgency campaigns.
Contractors, both armed and unarmed, also repre-
sent a serious military vulnerability. In the uprising in
Iraq during the spring of 2004, both Sunni and Shia
factions conducted major operations against coalition
forces. e insurgents eectively cut Allied supply
lines from Kuwait. U.S. forces faced signicant logis-
tics risks as a result. Despite the crisis, U.S. ocials
could not morally order unarmed logistics contrac-
tors to ght the opposition. e contractors lacked the
training, equipment, and legal status to do so. Had the
supply line been run by military forces, it would have
using contractors directly
undercuts both the legitimacy
and the authority of the host
nation government
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 9
been both moral and possible to order them to ght
through. Despite this demonstrated operational vul-
nerability, the fact that unarmed contractors are spe-
cically not obligated to ght has not been discussed
as a signicant risk in employing contractors rather
than military logistics organizations. Furthermore,
while military logistics units can provide their own
security in low-threat environments, unarmed con-
tractors cannot. e government must either assign
military forces or hire additional armed contractors to
provide that security.
e substitution of unarmed contractors for Sol-
diers and Marines creates yet another vulnerability: lack
of an emergency reserve. In the past, support troops
have been repeatedly employed in critical situations
to provide reinforcements for overwhelmed combat
troops. Contractors are simply unable to fulll this
emergency role. is limitation, as well as the unarmed
contractor’s inability to ght, is even more signicant in
conventional conicts than in irregular war.
Contracting also takes key elements of the counter-
insurgency eort out of the hands of the commander.
In the spring of 2010, ISAF determined that DynCorp
had failed in its contract to train and mentor the Afghan
police.
28
ISAF then put the contract out for competition.
General Stanley McChrystal, then-commander of ISAF,
stated that the police were one of the most critical ele-
ments of his campaign plan, so the contracting process
was accelerated. Not surprisingly, DynCorp did not win
the new contract. Since time is critical in Afghanistan,
plans were made to rapidly transition the contract to a
new provider to ensure that the Afghan police could play
their part in the counterinsurgency campaign. However,
DynCorp successfully protested the contract award.
29
us, it retains the training contract and will retain it
until all legal processes are exhausted. In short, the com-
mander lost control of one of the critical elements of
his counterinsurgency campaign at a critical time—and
there was nothing he could do about it. Despite Dyn-
Corp’s documented failure, at the time of this writing, it
remains in charge of police training and mentoring with
the full knowledge that as soon as possible ISAF will get
rid of DynCorp.
Contracts also fragment the chain of command. All
military units in a theater are under the command of a
military ocer, but contractors are not. While both con-
tractors and the government have worked hard to resolve
coordination issues, the fact remains that contractors are
not under military command. Complicating any attempt
to create unity of eort is the fact that contractors are in
direct competition with each other and treat a signicant
portion of the information concerning their operations
as proprietary information, which they will not share
with the government or their competitors.
Strategic Impact
Despite the numerous problems articulated above,
contractors will have an important and continuing role
in U.S. operations—both domestic and overseas. ere
are currently numerous important functions that the U.S.
Government is incapable of performing without con-
tractor support. is is not a new phenomenon. DOD—
particularly the Air Force and Navy—has long relied on
contractors to ll niche requirements such as maintain-
ing and, sometimes, even operating the newest high-
technology equipment. More recently, contractors have
been hired to execute many of the routine housekeeping
tasks at permanent U.S. military facilities.
However, despite conducting almost 9 years of com-
bat operations supported by contractors, the United States
still has not conducted a substantial examination of the
strategic impact the use of contractors has in counterin-
surgency. is does not mean contracts and contractors are
not being studied. Congress formed the Commission on
private security companies can
compete directly with host nation
attempts to recruit and retain
military and police personnel
10 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
Wartime Contracting specically “to assess a number of
factors related to wartime contracting, including the ex-
tent of waste, fraud, abuse, and mismanagement of war-
time contracts.”
30
Focused on improving the eciency of
wartime contracting, the commission did not discuss the
strategic impact of using contractors in its 2009 Interim
Report.
31
is author hopes that the commission will in-
clude the strategic impact in its nal report in 2011.
Within the executive branch, DOD and the Depart-
ment of State are conducting studies on how to reduce
fraud and increase the eciency of contractors. e Joint
Sta is running a major study to determine the level of
dependency on contractor support in contingency opera-
tions. Various Department of Justice investigations are go-
ing over past contracts for everything from fraud to abuse
of prisoners to inappropriate use of deadly force. Yet none
of these studies is looking at the fundamental questions
concerning the strategic impact of contractors in combat.
Contractors clearly can have a strategic impact on
the success of counterinsurgency operations in a vari-
ety of ways. e most important include reducing the
political capital necessary to commit U.S. forces to war;
potentially reducing the legitimacy of a counterinsur-
gency eort; and damaging the perceived morality of the
war eort. Rather than automatically defaulting to hir-
ing contractors as a relatively quick, easy, and politically
benign solution to an immediate problem, the United
States should rst answer several key strategic questions.
First, what is the impact of contractors on the initial
decision to go to war as well as the will to sustain the
conict? Contractors provide the ability to initiate and
sustain long-term conicts without the political eort
necessary to convince the American people a war is
worth ghting. us, the United States can enter a war
with less eort to build popular consensus. Most wars
will not require full-scale national mobilization, but
rather selective mobilization of both military and
civilian assets. Both proponents and opponents admit
that without contractors, the United States would
have required much greater mobilization efforts to
generate and support a force of 320,000 in Iraq (the
combined troop and contractor count) or a force of
over 210,000 in Afghanistan. The use of contractors
allowed us to conduct both wars with much less
domestic political debate.
But is this good? Should we seek methods that
make it easier to take the Nation to war? at appears
to be a bad idea when entering a protracted conict.
Insurgents understand that political will is the critical
vulnerability of the United States in irregular warfare.
ey have discussed this factor openly in their online
strategic forums for almost a decade.
32
Ensuring that
the American public understands the diculty of the
impending conict and is rmly behind the eort
should be an essential element in committing forces to
the 10 or more years that modern counterinsurgencies
require for success. us, while the use of contractors
lessens the extent of political mobilization needed, it
may well hurt the eort in the long term.
Second, as discussed earlier in this paper, con-
tractors can undermine the legitimacy of both U.S.
and host nation counterinsurgency eorts in a vari-
ety of ways. Field Manual 3–24, Counterinsurgency,
states that the conict is a competition for legitimacy
between the counterinsurgent and the insurgent.
33
Widespread use of contractors can directly undercut
a central theme of counterinsurgency doctrine. Under
certain conditions, we may choose to use contractors
in spite of the negative impact on legitimacy, but we
should not do so in ignorance of that impact. Any de-
cision to use contractors in a conict zone should be
carefully considered for its impact on the strategy that
while contractors and the
government have worked hard to
resolve coordination issues, the fact
remains that contractors are not
under military command
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 11
we have chosen and the campaign plan we are using to
execute that strategy.
A third area that needs strategic consideration is the
morality of using contractors. What are the moral im-
plications of authorizing contractors, qualied or not, to
use deadly force in the name of the United States? What
about hiring poor ird World citizens to sustain casual-
ties in support of U.S. policy? What is the U.S. respon-
sibility for wounded and killed contractors—particularly
those from the ird World? While these sound like the-
oretical questions, they are in fact practical ones. Main-
taining long-term domestic popular support for conict
requires that U.S. actions be both legitimate and moral.
Recommendations
Currently, the Commission on Wartime Con-
tracting (www.wartimecontracting.gov) is exam-
ining a broad range of issues concerning wartime
contracting and will present its nal report in 2011.
Of particular interest will be the reports nd-
ings on “inherently governmental functions that
should not be done by contractors. Even as the
commission continues its work, the manpower re-
quirements of the current conicts mean that, for the
near term, the United States will continue to employ
a large number of contractors in war zones. In fact, as
our forces draw down in Iraq, the State Department
has stated its requirement for security contractors will
increase signicantly.
34
Near-term operational imperatives and the poten-
tial negative strategic impacts discussed above highlight
the need for clear guidelines about when and how the
U.S. Government should employ contractors. is ques-
tion should be a central part of our post-Afghanistan
force structure discussions. e size and type of force
that we build for the future depend on a clear concept
of how the United States plans to use contractors, both
armed and unarmed, in present and future conicts.
is discussion cannot wait until the commissions re-
port is nalized and approved. e Secretary of Defense
is already pushing the department to reduce its budget
signicantly. e debate about future force structure is
well under way.
A number of factors are putting major pressure on
force structure planners. e primary pressure will be the
falling budgets that Secretary Robert Gates has clearly
warned the Services to expect. In addition, as U.S. forces
begin to withdraw from Afghanistan, force planners
will have to decide how to allocate limited resources to
position the Armed Forces to deal with future conicts.
ere is an intense, ongoing debate about which types
of conicts should take priority and then how the forces
should be structured, equipped, and trained to deal with
those contingencies. A tempting way to avoid tough
decisions will be to assume contractors will provide major
services across the spectrum of conict, thus dramatically
reducing the force requirements for logistics and security.
In the past, we have often sacriced force structure to
save weapons systems. Planning to use contractors in
future conict zones would reinforce this tendency.
Any force planning documents should clearly state
what assumptions have been made concerning the func-
tions of the contractors who will support the force. e
following guidelines should be employed in considering
when and how to use contractors in the future.
e U.S. Governments default position should
be no contractors outside the wire” in a conict zone.
Contractor presence outside secure facilities places
them in direct contact with the population. Contractors
can undercut the legitimacy of the host nation govern-
ment, reduce the accountability of the U.S. Government
for actions taken in its name, irritate the population,
compete directly for the most competent local person-
nel, fragment the chain of command, provide an excuse
for forming local militias, and are dicult to re—even
widespread use of contractors can
directly undercut a central theme of
counterinsurgency doctrine
12 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
when ineective. Given these issues, the United States
should strive to keep contractors out of conict zones.
is will not always be possible but should be the stan-
dard. Most of the problems highlighted in this paper
occurred in conict zones. e unique stresses on the
contractors combined with the severe limitations on
the governments ability to oversee their performance
resulted in repeated actions that reduced operational ef-
fectiveness and undercut the U.S. strategic position. e
cost savings of using contractors are uncertain at best.
In contrast, the strategic and operational problems that
arise from using them in a counterinsurgency are clear
and documented.
e U.S. Government is unlikely to have enough
government employees to perform the numerous house-
keeping functions—mess, laundry, cleaning, and so
forth—that are an integral part of any operation. ere-
fore, the default position should remain that we hire con-
tractors only for those functions that take place within a
secure facility and require minimum contact with host
nation personnel. is means that DOD must be able
to provide security for other U.S. Government organiza-
tions working in conict zones until such time as they
can hire and train sucient government security person-
nel. Exceptions to this rule should be closely examined.
is position must be an explicit factor in force structure
planning. e one consistent exception to this rule will
be interpreters since the U.S. Government simply can-
not maintain sucient linguistic capability for the wide
range of possible future commitments.
If U.S. Government capacity is exceeded, the default
position should become using host nation organizations
rst and host nation contractors next with U.S. or for-
eign contractors being a choice of last resort. As noted,
even with a default position of not hiring contractors in
conict zones, some elements of the government would
most likely hire contractors, including armed contractors,
in future conicts. Some agencies could determine that
they cannot achieve an assigned task without contrac-
tors and would be unable to get other U.S. Government
partners to take the mission. To minimize the negative
impact of contractors in irregular war, policy should give
strong preference to the host nation providing the ser-
vices—even if they have to be funded and supported by
the United States.
Examples where local contractors should be rst
choice are inside secure facilities and as xed point se-
curity. Many of the jobs contractors perform inside fa-
cilities—meal preparation, cleaning—can easily be done
by local labor. Since local contractors would commute to
and from work, hiring them would require more eort
be dedicated to security than the current practice of im-
porting South Asian laborers and keeping them on base.
However, hiring local laborers provides economic stimu-
lus. In addition, the xed point security mission may well
be appropriate for local personnel because these jobs re-
quire little training and, because they are in a xed posi-
tion, are easier to supervise. e primary eort should be
to train local personnel to execute such jobs with those
security personnel transitioning to the appropriate host
nation government authority as soon as possible. Tran-
sitioning supervision of these personnel to local govern-
ments could be easier than doing so with regular army
or police. However, caution must be exercised whenever
considering armed contractors because the very act of the
government hiring contractors legitimizes the private use
of force. If a government needs to hire armed protection,
then it is dicult to deny businesses, political parties,
and other entities the right to hire armed contractors. In
both Iraq and Afghanistan, this dynamic led to private
militias that work for local strongmen rather than a local
community. NGOs, who often have been forced to hire
contractors as the security situation deteriorates, would
the size and type of force that
we build depend on a clear concept
of how the United States plans to
use contractors in present
and future conicts
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 13
continue to insist on protecting their people. us, a ma-
jor focus of the initial eort must be to replace contract
security with government-provided security.
In cases where the host nation lacks the necessary
capacity, local companies and personnel should receive
strong preference. In irregular war, it is important that
these jobs be assigned to the local population both to
stimulate economic growth and provide alternatives to
insurgent employment for local males. While such con-
tracts may be necessary, maximum eort should be made
to ensure that responsibilities are transferred to the host
nation government personnel as early as possible. Even
as host nation government capacity grows, there may be
some jobs that require local security contractors. In Af-
ghanistan, escorting logistics convoys from Pakistan to
Afghanistan falls into this category. e historical record
indicates ISAF or the Afghan government would require
massive forces to accomplish the mission. e Afghan
security companies” have succeeded at this task, but op-
erate outside ISAF rules of engagement, upset local pow-
er structures, and can create additional enemies. Future
use of local security companies for such missions must
be carefully balanced against their negative side-eects
and employed only when there is no other solution. If
President Karzai enforces his order that contract security
cease operations by December 2010, this may provide a
valuable case study in how government forces can replace
armed contractors or the negative impacts if they attempt
to replace contractors but lack the capacity to do so.
e default position should be to hire contractors or
U.S. Government civilian employees to ll those billets
requiring deployment to locations outside the conict
zone. One of the greatest problems the U.S. military
faces in protracted war is personnel tempo—the period
Service personnel spend away from home. By hiring
contractors to ll jobs overseas but outside the conict
zone, the United States can reduce the personnel tempo
of the uniformed forces. Our current use of contractors
in Kuwait is a good example of this approach. While
deployments to Kuwait to support the eort in Iraq are
not dangerous, they do increase the personnel tempo of
the uniformed Services. us, DOD has lled most of
these billets with contractors, who have compiled a very
good record running the training, maintenance, and
transit facilities in Kuwait. is type of well-dened,
repetitive administrative task is ideal for contractors
particularly in a forward-deployed, nonconict loca-
tion. Furthermore, the contractors, like all expatriates
working in the country, are subject to Kuwaits legal
system, and thus, the local population sees them as ac-
countable to Kuwait authority.
Aggressive eorts should be made to use either
DOD civilian employees or contractors to ll nonde-
ploying military billets. As stated, personnel tempo is a
major problem for the Services. Yet the Defense Busi-
ness Board noted that, despite 9 years of conict, fully
40 percent of Active-duty personnel have not deployed
to a conict zone, and an additional 30 percent have de-
ployed only once.
35
While a signicant number of these
nondeployers are rst-term personnel who have not yet
received sucient training to deploy, the number of ca-
reer force personnel who have not deployed is still high.
ese personnel are lling nondeploying billets. Rather
than hiring contractors to ll billets inside the conict
zone, we need to examine which of these nondeploying
billets can be lled by contractors, freeing uniformed
personnel to deploy.
If contractors are required, they must be under the
direct supervision of a U.S. Government employee. While
the government is making strenuous eorts to increase
the number of contracting ocers and to become more
specic in writing contracts, the fact remains that the
government cannot control contractor actions without
direct supervision. Unless it has direct supervision, the
if a government needs to hire armed
protection, then it is difcult to
deny other entities the right to hire
armed contractors
14 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
government will remain unaware of contractors whose
actions alienate the local population or fail to meet U.S.
standards. e degree of supervision will vary with the
type of work being done. Routine maintenance work in
a secure facility would require only normal contracting
oversight. Armed escorts or drivers who are in regular
contact with civilian populations would require constant
supervision in the form of a government employee rid-
ing with each vehicle and commanding each convoy. is
would give rise to a number of problems such as having a
government employee making less money but taking the
same risks as a contractor or having a less experienced
government employee supervising a more experienced
and often older contractor. However, these are minor
problems compared to those created by the populations
perception of unsupervised contractors.
Long-term Requirement
is paper has focused on the current U.S. use of
contractors in conict zones, but the use of armed con-
tractors is on the rise around the world. Led by the Unit-
ed States, many nations have reintroduced armed con-
tractors to conict zones. In addition, the lack of security
in undergoverned areas has led NGOs, international or-
ganizations, private companies, and even nation-states to
hire armed contractors to provide security and unarmed
contractors to deliver services. In some cases, it is dif-
cult to tell if contractors are part of a private rm or
are hired by a government that does not wish to send of-
cial government personnel. e most serious potential
problems arise from the fact that large numbers of armed
contractors are being injected into an international secu-
rity arena that lacks recent experience in regulating them.
Armed contractors are having a global impact well
beyond that of the two irregular wars America is ghting.
Armed contractors introduce a new element into
international relations. Current international law and
international organizations such as the United Nations
have developed protocols and procedures for dealing
with the use of the armed forces of nation-states as well
as insurgents. However, these same organizations have
a paucity of experience in dealing with the introduction
of armed contractors into a conict zone whether those
contractors are hired by a private rm or a nation-state.
is leads to a nal recommendation.
e United States must develop policies and pro-
cedures to deal with the presence of armed contrac-
tors in conict zones. Because these armed entities
are generally outside the experience and mandate of
current international organizations and mechanisms,
they will continue to have unforeseen impacts. us,
the United States must work with other states, NGOs,
and international organizations to develop policies,
procedures, and institutions to deal with the presence
of armed contractors in conict zones. e Montreux
Document is an example of such an eort and de-
serves the support of the United States.
36
However, it
is only the rst step in learning to manage these new
players in the international arena.
Notes
1
Moshe Schwartz, Department of Defense Contractors in
Iraq and Afghanistan: Background and Analysis (Washington, DC:
Congressional Research Service, July 2, 2010), 5.
2
Congressional Budget Oce, “Contractors Support of U.S.
Operations in Iraq,” table 2, available at <www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/96xx/
doc9688/MainText.3.1.shtml>.
3
Schwartz, 5.
4
Peter W. Singer, “e Dark Truth About Blackwater,”
Salon, October 2, 2007, available at <www.salon.com/news/fea-
ture/2007/10/02/blackwater/print.html>.
5
Dan Baum, “Nation Builders for Hire,” e New York Times,
June 22, 2003, available at <www.informationclearinghouse.info/
article3905.htm>.
6
Wising up, moving out,” Jane’s Defence Weekly, July 1, 2009, 29.
7
Steve Fainaru, “Private War: Convoy to Darkness,” e Wash-
ington Post, July 29, 2007, 1.
8
See <http://icasualties.org> and <www.propublica.org/series/
disposable-army>.
9
Steven L. Schooner and Colin D. Swan, “Contractors and the
Ultimate Sacrice,” Service Contractor, September 2010, 17.
10
Singer.
if contractors are required, they
must be under the direct supervision
of a U.S. Government employee
www.ndu.edu/inss SF No. 260 15
11
Department of Labor, Oce of Workers Compensation
Programs, available at <www.dol.gov/owcp/dlhwc/lsaboutdbareports.
htm>.
12
David Isenberg, Private Military Contractors and U.S. Grand
Strategy (Oslo, Norway: International Peace Research Institute, Janu-
ary 2009), 5.
13
Jennifer K. Elsea, Moshe Schwartz, and Kennon H. Naka-
mura, Private Security Contractors in Iraq: Background, Legal Status,
and Other Issues (Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service,
updated August 25, 2008), 49.
14
David H. Petraeus, “COMISAFs Counterinsurgency (COIN)
Contracting Guidance,” Kabul, Afghanistan, September 8, 2010.
15
Author’s experience while serving on Coalition Military As-
sistance Training Team in Iraq during early 2004.
16
Elsea, Schwartz, and Nakamura, 15–31.
17
ere are a limited number of cases where armed contractor
action can increase the legitimacy of a government—for instance,
protecting a hospital or refugee camp. However, even in these benign
cases, the presence of contractors shows the government cannot
protect its people and opens the door for any business or association
to hire its own armed guards—in essence a private militia.
18
Elsea, Schwartz, and Nakamura, 13–14.
19
Afghans identify themselves by qawm, rather than by tribe
or nationality. A qawm identity is based on kinship, residence, and
sometimes occupation. Although qawm is sometimes translated
into English as tribe, the qawm relationship may cross tribal or even
ethnic boundaries. e qawm is the basic unit of social community
in Afghanistan, but the relationships involved can vary from ethnic
group to ethnic group.
20
Dexter Filkins, With U.S. Aid, Warlord Builds Afghan Em-
pire,” e New York Times, June 6, 2010, available at <www.nytimes.
com/2010/06/06/world/asia/06warlords.html>.
21
Nicholas Pelham, “Contractors in Iraq Accused of Import-
ing Labor and Exporting Prot,” Financial Times, October 14, 2003,
available at <www.commondreams.org/headlines03/1014-01.htm>.
22
Matt Waldman, “Falling Short: Aid Eectiveness in Af-
ghanistan,” available at <www.acbar.org/ACBAR%20Publications/
ACBAR%20Aid%20Eectiveness%20(25%20Mar%2008).pdf>.
23
Roya Wolverson, “Not So Helpful,” Newsweek, November 24,
2007, available at <www.newsweek.com/id/72068>.
24
Carl Forsberg and Kimberly Kagan, “Consolidating Private
Security Companies in South Afghanistan, Institute for the Study
of War, May 28, 2010, accessed at <www.understandingwar.org/les/
BackgrounderPSC.pdf>.
25
Afghan-Cda Security Firms,” e Canadian Press-Broadcast
Wire, January 25, 2010, document BNW0000020100126e61p00011.
26
Major General Nick Carters Defense Department brieng via
teleconference from Afghanistan, May 26, 2010.
27
Afghan Leader to Ban Security Contractors,” August 16,
2010, available at <www.cbsnews.com/stories/2010/08/16/world/
main6776999.shtml>.
28
Pratap Chatterchee, “DynCorp Oversight in Afghanistan
Faulted,” available at <www.ipsnews.net/news.asp?idnews=50477>.
29
Government Accountability Oce Press Summary, “Deci-
sion on Bid Protest by DynCorp International Regarding U.S.
Army Contracts in Afghanistan,” available at <www.gao.gov/press/
dyncorp_2010mar15.html>.
30
e Commission on Wartime Contracting in Iraq and Af-
ghanistan, available at <www.wartimecontracting.gov>.
31
Ibid.,At What Cost? Contingency Contracting in Iraq and
Afghanistan,” June 2009, available at <www.wartimecontracting.gov/
docs/CWC_Interim_Report_At_What_Cost_06-10-09.pdf>.
32
Middle East Media Research Institute, “Bin Laden Lieu-
tenant Admits to September 11 and Explains Al-Qa’idas Combat
Doctrine,” February 20, 2002, available at <www.memri.org/report/
en/0/0/0/0/0/0/607.htm>.
33
Field Manual 3–24/Marine Corps Warghting Publication
3.33–5, Counterinsurgency (Washington, DC: Headquarters Depart-
ment of the Army, December 2006), 1–1.
34
William Matthews, “U.S. Contractor Use in Iraq Expected to
Rise,” Defense News, July 12, 2010, available at <www.defensenews.
com/story.php?i=4704826>.
35
Defense Business Board, “Reducing Overhead and Improv-
ing Business Operations. Initial Observations,” accessed at <http://
defensenewsstand.com/showdoc.asp?docid=5192010_may19a>.
36
See e Montreux Document (Geneva, Switzerland: Inter-
national Committee of the Red Cross, August 2009), available at
<www.icrc.org/web/eng/siteeng0.nsf/htmlall/montreux-document-
170908/$FILE/ICRC_002_0996.pdf>.
The Center for Strategic Research within the Institute for
National Strategic Studies provides advice to the Secre-
tary of Defense, Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff, and
unied combatant commands through studies, reports,
briengs, and memoranda. The center conducts directed
research and analysis in the areas of strategic and region-
al studies and engages in independent and leading-edge
research and analysis in related areas.
The Strategic Forum series presents original research
by members of NDU as well as other scholars and
specialists in national security affairs from the United
States and abroad. The opinions, conclusions, and recom-
mendations expressed or implied within are those of the
contributors and do not necessarily reect the views of the
Defense Department or any other agency of the Federal
Government. Visit NDU Press online at www.ndupress.edu.
Christopher J. Lamb
Director
Center for Strategic Research
Phillip C. Saunders
Director of Research
Center for Strategic Research
Dr. Hans Binnendijk
Director
INSS
INSTITUTE FOR NATIONAL STRATEGIC STUDIES
16 SF No. 260 www.ndu.edu/inss
Global Commons and Domain
Interrelationships: Time for a
New Conceptual Framework?
Mark E. Redden and Michael P. Hughes
(No. 259, October 2010)
Reforming the Inter-American
Defense Board
John A. Cope
(No. 258, August 2010)
Somalia’s Endless Transition:
Breaking the Deadlock
Andre Le Sage
(No. 257, June 2010)
Prioritizing Strategic Interests
in South Asia
Robert B. Oakley and T.X. Hammes
(No. 256, June 2010)
Africa’s Irregular Security
Threats: Challenges for U.S.
Engagement
Andre Le Sage
(No. 255, May 2010)
U.S.-Mexico Homeland Defense:
A Compatible Interface
Victor E. Renuart, Jr., and Biff Baker
(No. 254, February 2010)
Strengthening the IAEA:
How the Nuclear Watchdog
Can Regain Its Bark
Gregory L. Schulte
(No. 253, March 2010)
Avoiding a Crisis of Confidence
in the U.S. Nuclear Deterrent
John P. Caves, Jr.
(No. 252, January 2010)
U.S.-Cambodia Defense
Relations: Defining New
Possibilities
Lewis M. Stern
(No. 251, December 2009)
North Korea: Challenges,
Interests, and Policy
James J. Przystup
(No. 250, November 2009)
Burma in Strategic Perspective:
Renewing Discussion of Options
Lewis M. Stern, George Thomas, and Julia
A. Thompson
(No. 249, October 2009)
Unity of Effort: Key to Success
in Afghanistan
Christopher J. Lamb and Martin Cinnamond
(No. 248, September 2009)
Other titles from
NDU Press
For online access to NDU Press
publications, go to: ndupress.ndu.edu