This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists
and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments.
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal
Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Staff Reports
Credit Supply and the Rise in College
Tuition: Evidence from the Expansion in
Federal Student Aid Programs
David O. Lucca
Taylor Nadauld
Karen Shen
Staff Report No. 733
July 2015
Revised February 2017
Credit Supply and the Rise in College Tuition: Evidence from the Expansion in Federal
Student Aid Programs
David O. Lucca, Taylor Nadauld, and Karen Shen
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 733
July 2015; revised February 2017
JEL classification: G28, I22
Abstract
We study the link between the student credit expansion of the past fifteen years and the
contemporaneous rise in college tuition. To disentangle simultaneity issues, we analyze the
effects of increases in federal student loan caps using detailed student-level financial data. We
find a pass-through effect on tuition of changes in subsidized loan maximums of about 60 cents
on the dollar, and smaller but positive effects for unsubsidized federal loans. The subsidized loan
effect is most pronounced for more expensive degrees, those offered by private institutions, and
for two-year or vocational programs.
Key words: student loans, college tuition
_________________
Lucca: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (e-mail: david.lucca@ny.frb.org). Nadauld: Brigham
Young University (e-mail: taylor.nadauld@byu.edu). Shen: Harvard University (e-mail:
[email protected]ard.edu). The authors thank Brian Melzer (discussant), Ian Fillmore, Paul
Goldsmith-Pinkham, Erik Hurst, Lance Lochner, Christopher Palmer (discussant), Johannes
Stroebel (discussant), Sarah Turner, and seminar participants at the American Finance
Association’s 2016 annual meeting, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Brigham Young
University, the NBER 2015 SI Corporate Finance Workshop, and the Julis-Rabinowitz Center
for Public Policy and Finance’s Annual Conference for helpful comments and discussions. The
authors also thank Carter Davis for providing excellent research assistance. The views expressed
in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.
1 Introduction
The existence of a causal link between student loan availability and college tuition has been
the subject of policy discussion and debate for at least three decades (Bennett, 1987, for example),
and has been no less relevant in recent years as tuition and student loan balances have continued
to significantly outpace overall inflation. Average sticker-price tuition rose 46% in constant 2012
dollars between 2001 and 2012 (Figure 1), and despite a sharp deleveraging of other sources of
debt by U.S. households after the Great Recession, student debt has continued to grow unabated,
and now represents the largest form of non-mortgage liability for households (Figure 2). While
rising tuition almost certainly contributes to increased demand for student loans, an important
policy question is whether student loan supply may also allow tuition to rise as postulated by the
so-called “Bennett Hypothesis.
1
In this paper, we propose an identification strategy to isolate the effect of student loans on
tuition. We use variation in student credit supply that resulted from legislative changes in the
maximum amounts students are eligible to borrow from the federal subsidized and unsubsidized
loan programs. These policy changes went into effect in the 2007-08 and 2008-09 school years and
led to a large credit expansion, as these program maximums had remained unchanged since the
early 1990s.
2
Exploiting the federal increase in credit supply for identification presents two chal-
lenges. First, the increase in program maximums affected students at all institutions. Second, we
only have reliable time series data on the sticker-price of tuition rather than the net tuition paid by
students after accounting for scholarships or discounts to lower-income students. In an illustra-
tive model, however, we show that even when universities price-discriminate, a credit expansion
will raise tuition paid by all students, not just students borrowing at the federal loan caps, because
of pecuniary demand externalities. We also show that the tuition effects will be larger at schools
1
The then-Secretary of Education William Bennett (1987) argued that “[...] increases in financial aid in recent years
have enabled colleges and universities blithely to raise their tuitions, confident that Federal loan subsidies would help
cushion the increase,” a statement that came to be known as the “Bennett Hypothesis.
2
The maximum subsidized federal loan amount for freshmen rose in the 2007-08 academic year from $2,625 to $3,500,
and for sophomores from $3,500 to $4,500; unsubsidized loan maximums rose by $2,000 in the academic year 2008-09.
Pell Grant maximums, which is not our main focus but that we control for, rose gradually between the 2007-2008 and
2010-2011 school years as well as in prior years as a result of the yearly appropriation process of the Department of Ed-
ucation. Subsidized, unsubsidized loans and Pell Grants are the main “Title IV” programs. We discuss the institutional
details of federal aid programs in Section 3.
1
serving a more credit-constrained population. We use these predictions to identify the impact of
loan supply increases on tuition by constructing an institutions “exposure,” or treatment intensity,
to a policy change using detailed student-level data. We then interact our exposure measure with
the timing of shifts in the supply of federal student aid, with an approach similar to Card (1999)’s
analysis of changes in national minimum wage standards.
We first validate our approach by documenting that institution-level loan amounts respond
to the interaction of the legislated changes in maximum aid amounts with an institution’s expo-
sure to the changes. Changes in per-student subsidized (unsubsidized) loan amounts measured
at the institution level load with a coefficient of .7 (.6) on yearly changes in the maximums per
qualifying student. We next study the response of tuition to the interaction of policy changes and
treatment intensity to examine tuition increases in the same year as the credit expansions. We find
that increases in institution-specific subsidized (unsubsidized) loan maximums lead to a sticker-
price increase of about 60 (40) cents on the dollar. This effect represents the additional amount that
institutions raised their tuition in the years of the policy changes relative to what would have been
expected without the policy change, which we measure using institutional fixed effects to capture
the average tuition increases at an institution. All of these effects are highly significant and con-
sistent with the Bennett Hypothesis, and apply to a large sample of all Title IV institutions. Direct
quotes from earnings calls and large stock market reactions to the passing of these loan expansions
lend additional support to these findings for the subset of publicly traded for-profit institutions.
The effect that we document is particularly interesting because it is evidence of a cross-demand
effect of a credit expansion through a pecuniary externality with a relaxation of the borrowing con-
straint for some students affecting pricing to other students. Of course, institutions may have miti-
gated the effect of these increases through increases in institutional grants to some or all students.
Though institutional grant data is not available for our entire sample, we find that an increase in
subsidized loans actually decreased institutional grants by about 20 cents on the dollar (compared
to an effect of about 30 cents for Pell Grants) for the subset of institutions that report grant amounts,
suggesting that the tuition effect is on average not canceled out, and may even be amplified, by in-
stitutional grants, though we cannot observe the distribution of grants.
2
In robustness checks and alternative specifications, we attempt to address concerns that other
variables may be driving the behavior we observe. First of all, our specifications control for changes
in Pell Grant maximums, which partially overlapped with changes in the federal loan policies.
Second, we address issues relating to the parallel trends assumption in a few ways. One obvious
concern is that the Great Recession may have may have boosted demand for education services
at institutions where students are more dependent on student aid, or on the supply side, these
same institutions may have experienced a drop in state appropriations or endowments, requiring
an increase in tuition to bolster budgets. However, tuition decisions for the year when the main
policy took effect, academic year 2007-2008, predated the recession, as tuition is typically set in the
first half of each calendar year. We provide estimates that drop the later years in our sample as a
robustness check. Using the full sample, we also try to control for the differential characteristics of
schools that may be driving differential variation in these years by interacting policy changes with
other institution-characteristics such as changes in non-tuition funding sources, selectivity, cost,
type of programs offered, or average student income. Our final robustness check is agnostic about
what variables might be driving the differential variation and shows that the difference between
this institution is indeed starkest in the policy years. We run placebo regressions that comparing
tuition changes of highly and less exposed institutions outside the years of policy changes. We find
that the subsidized loan effect is robust across specifications both in magnitude and significance,
and passes the placebo test, but find that the unsubsidized loan effects are less robust to these
controls and tests.
In addition, we investigate the characteristics of the institutions where the passthrough effect of
credit to tuition are most pronounced. We find that the subsidized loan effect is most pronounced
for more expensive degrees, those offered by private institutions, and for two-year or vocational
programs. Finally, in a larger sample we focus on for-profit institutions, which, despite having re-
ceived much attention in the policy debate, are heavily underrepresented in our main data sources.
We document abnormally large tuition increases by this sector relative to other years and other sec-
tors, providing suggestive evidence that for-profits institutions, which rely heavily on federal aid,
were highly responsive to these credit expansions.
3
Related literature. This paper contributes to three main strands of literature. First, it builds on the
expanding finance literature studying the role of credit supply on real allocations and prices. Much
attention has been devoted to this question in the context of the housing market, for which credit
is central, in an attempt to establish whether the U.S. housing boom of 2002-6 and the ensuing
bust can be explained by increased credit to subprime borrowers (see, for example, Mian and Sufi,
2009; Adelino, Schoar, and Severino, 2012; Favara and Imbs, 2015). From a finance perspective, the
market for postsecondary education has shared several features with the housing market despite
the important difference that student loans fund a capital investment while mortgages fund an
asset. Like housing finance, credit plays a key role in funding U.S. postsecondary education, and
most of this credit is originated through government-sponsored programs. Our paper provides
complementary evidence to the conjecture that credit expansions can result in aggregate pricing
effects and not just on assets purchased by credit recipients.
This paper also contributes to the economics of education literature studying the determinants
of the price of postsecondary education, and in particular, the strand of this literature that seeks
to accept or reject the “Bennett Hypothesis. The literature on this topic has thus far not reached a
consensus. The majority of these studies have focused on the effect of Pell Grants on sticker tuition
3
,
though other studies have used individual-level data to look for evidence that grant programs and
tax credits may displace institutional grants that would otherwise lower the net tuition paid by aid
recipients.
4
Our study is one of only a few to look at the impact of loan programs. Cellini and
Goldin (2014) study the impact of overall federal aid eligibility by constructing a dataset of compa-
rable eligible and ineligible for-profit institutions and show that eligible institutions charge tuition
that is about 75 percent higher than comparable institutions whose students cannot apply for such
3
For example, McPherson and Schapiro (1991), looking at the period 1979-1986, find no evidence of the Bennett hy-
pothesis for private four-year institutions, but find a pass-through of $50 for every $100 for public four-year institutions.
Singell and Stone (2007) find increases at private institutions but only in out-of-state tuition at public institutions using
data from 1989 to 1996. Rizzo and Ehrenberg (2003) find evidence of the Bennett Hypothesis in in-state tuition, but not
out-of-state tuition in a restricted sample of 91 public flagship state universities between 1979 and 1998.
4
For example, Turner (2014) uses a regression discontinuity approach and finds that institutions alter institutional
aid (scholarships) as a means of capturing the federal aid provided through the federal Pell Grant program. Similar
studies have also found evidence of the Bennett Hypothesis in tax credits (Long (2004b), Turner (2014)), and state grant
aid programs (Long (2004a)). A review of some of these and other studies of the Bennett Hypothesis can be found in
Congressional Research Service (2014).
4
aid. Because almost all degree-granting institutions are federal-aid-eligible, their study is mostly
limited to vocational programs. Our study looks instead at variation within eligible institutions
(and thus includes two- and four-year degree programs), and also attempts to specifically isolate
the role of student loans. The only studies to have explored this question specifically have used
structural methods, e.g. Epple et al. (2013) and Gordon and Hedlund (2016). Both find that in-
creases in borrowing limits generate tuition increases, with the latter finding that borrowing limit
increases represent the single most important factor in explaining tuition increases between 1987
and 2010 at four-year institutions, explaining 40% of the tuition increase, while supply-side factors
such as rising costs or falling state appropriations have much less explanatory power. Our study
complements these studies by using a natural experiment approach.
Finally, this paper is related to the public economics literature on tax incidence (Kotlikoff and
Summers, 1987), which studies how the burden of a particular tax is allocated among agents after
accounting for partial and general equilibrium effects. In our setting, the student aid expansion is
a disbursement of a public benefit. From an individual perspective, more aid is beneficial because
of relaxed constraints, but in equilibrium the welfare effects of aid recipients could be negative
because of the sizable and offsetting tuition effect.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the illustrative model,
Section 3 provides institutional detail on federal aid programs and caps, and Section 4 introduces
the data. Section 5 describes the empirical method. Section 6 discusses the main results in the
paper, while Section 7 presents robustness specifications, studies attributes of institutions with the
highest passthrough for the subsidized program and additional evidence for for-profits institu-
tions. Finally, Section 8 concludes.
2 Model
We present an illustrative model to explain how increased student loan supply may affect
sticker tuition, as well as the empirical identification assumption. A distinguishing feature of col-
lege pricing is the extent to which price discrimination takes place, with universities often using
scholarships, grants, or other mechanisms to offer different prices to students of different incomes,
skills, or backgrounds. Eligibility for most federal student aid, on the other hand, is based solely
5
on income considerations. We consider a school that conditions tuition offers on students’ observ-
able characteristics. In the model, an increase in the federal student loan maximum boosts demand
from lower-income students by relaxing their borrowing constraints. In equilibrium, the increased
ability to pay raises tuition for all students, and not just for the aid recipients. This pecuniary de-
mand externality is an important feature of the model, to explain how sticker price responds to
changes in federal loans, although aid recipients are likely charged discounted prices rather than
sticker. The tuition effect is also largest for universities in which a large number of students are
exposed to the policy change, a result that we use in the empirical section to identify the effects of
an increase in loan maximums on sticker tuition.
To simplify the exposition, we assume that short-run school capacity is fixed at N seats, so
schools only decide whom to admit and what tuition to charge them. In reality short-run seat
supply is imperfectly elastic rather than fixed, but only this more general assumption is needed for
our main model predictions. Schools observe coarse measures of student characteristics along two
dimensions: quality and income. A student i can be of high-quality, q
H
, or low-quality, q
L
, and
either income-constrained, n
C
, or unconstrained, n
U
. A fraction of students s is constrained, and
a fraction r is low-quality, and for simplicity the two characteristics are uncorrelated. We assume
a population 1 of potential students and that student type is sufficiently large so schools can pick
any type distribution, or N < min(s , 1 s, r, 1 r). Schools make tuition offers conditional on
observables, meaning students at a school pay one of four tuition levels t(q
i
, n
i
).
Students accept a school’s tuition offer if their valuation of the school exceeds the tuition cost,
and if they are able to afford the tuition cost given their income and aid. Thus, in addition to af-
fecting the tuition they are charged, students quality and income also determine their decision
to attend. A student i’s valuation of a school’s offer depends negatively on her observed qual-
ity, because a high-quality student is likely to have better offers from other schools or employers.
Additional unobserved components to both quality and income are present to capture residual
uncertainty for a school as to whether a student accepts an offer and its ability to extract rent as
in standard third-degree price discrimination models (Tirole, 1988). The idiosyncratic unobserved
component to a student’s valuation of a school’s offer is distributed as v
i
Exp(δ), and she is
6
willing to accept the school’s offer when:
v
i
q
i
t(q
i
, n
i
) (1)
Similarly, we assume that a student’s unobservable income shock is distributed as W
i
Exp(ω).
Constrained students are offered a federal student loan of balance B and thus can afford to attend
if their income and aid are such that:
5
W
i
+ n
i
t(q
i
, n
C
) B, (2)
An unconstrained student does not face a financial constraint and does not qualify for federal aid,
i.e. W
U
is sufficiently large that the financial constraint corresponding to (2) never binds. Because
of the unobservable components, a school does not know with certainty whether a student accepts
an offer. The demand from a high-income student with quality q
i
is then equal to the probability
that the student’s unobserved valuation is sufficiently high:
d(q
i
, n
U
) = P(v
i
t + q
i
) = e
δ(t+q
i
)
(3)
while the demand from a low-income student with quality q
i
is equal to the joint probability of a
sufficiently high school valuation and income shock:
d(q
i
, n
C
) = P(v
i
t + q
i
)P(W t B n
C
) = e
δ(t+q
i
)ω(tBn
C
)
(4)
where t = t(q
i
, n
i
). The corresponding total demand functions from the four combinations of
income and skills are given by the product of individual demands and the mass of students of each
type combination.
6
Demand elasticities are δ for unconstrained students, and δ + ω for constrained
5
We are assuming that the interest charged is zero, as it is the case, for example for subsidized loan recipients when
the student is in school. We are also assuming a fixed loan balance. In practice the loan balance is capped by the smaller
of the loan maximum and the gap between cost of attendance and family contribution. We are therefore considering
the case in which tuition levels are sufficiently high. This assumption can be relaxed.
6
These are: D
H,U
= (1 s)(1 r) d(q
H
, n
U
); D
L,U
= (1 s)r d(q
L
, n
U
); D
H,C
= s(1 r) d(q
H
, n
C
); D
L,C
=
sr d(q
L
, n
C
).
7
ones. Also let D
H
, D
L
, D
U
, and D
C
be the sums of the corresponding demand elements, or the
aggregate demand from high-quality, low-quality, unconstrained, or constrained students, and D
be the sum of all these terms.
We assume that colleges maximize a combination of student quality and revenues as in Epple,
Romano, and Sieg (2006):
7
max
t(q,n)
γN
1
( q
H
D
H
+ q
L
D
L
) + (1 γ)(
(q,n)
t(q, n )D
q,n
cD)
subject to:
D N, (5)
where γ is the weight placed by the school on the average quality of its student population, and
1 γ is the weight on profits. The school incurs a unit cost c to provide a seat up to its maximum
capacity N. The equilibrium levels of t are obtained from the first order conditions of this objective
function:
Proposition 1. Let λ be the Lagrange multiplier on (5). Then the optimal tuition levels satisfy:
t
q,U
= c +
1
δ
qγ
(1 γ)
+
λ
1 γ
,
t
q,C
= c +
1
δ + ω
qγ
(1 γ)
+
λ
1 γ
. (6)
All proofs are provided in Appendix A. This proposition states that the tuition charged to each
group of students is a markup over marginal cost c that is inversely related to their demand elas-
ticity and to their quality. Thus, lower quality students pay higher markups, as do less constrained
students who have lower demand elasticities.
To study how an increase in B may affect tuition, note that from (4) an increase in the borrowing
cap leads to an upward parallel shift of the demand curve for given t. It follows, that increasing
the borrowing amount B affects equilibrium tuition through the shadow cost of a seat and that the
7
In Epple et al. (2006) schools maximize investment expenditure on students rather than revenues, but also balance
annual budgets so that the two conditions are equivalent. See also Gordon and Hedlund (2016) for similar modeling
assumptions.
8
effect is the same for all types of students:
Proposition 2. An increase in the federal loan amount B leads to equal increases in t
H,U
, t
L,U
, t
H,C
and
t
L,C
:
t(q, n)
B
=
1
1 γ
λ
B
=
D
C
ω
δN + D
C
ω
> 0 (7)
for q
{
H, L
}
, n
{
U, C
}
.
The fact that the tuition effects are exactly equal relies on our specific assumption that all C stu-
dents borrow the exact same amount, but the general prediction that there is a price effect across
types from relaxing the constraint for the constrained type holds even when we relax this assump-
tion.
In the empirical section, we study the response of tuition to an increase in federal student loan
caps, which we model here as an increase in B. If loan maximums were the only factor influencing
tuition, estimates of (7) could be backed out from average tuition increases in years when loan
maximums were raised. However, since tuition trends are influenced by many other factors (e.g.
the business cycle, changes in the returns to higher education, etc.), we abstract from these omitted
variables using a difference-in-differences approach that exploits cross-sectional differences in the
sensitivity of tuition changes to an increase in B. From (7), the effect of B on tuition is greater
the more C students attend (D
C
/N) and the higher the elasticity of C students versus U students
((δ + ω)/δ). While elasticity differences are hard to measure, we use data on the share of aid
recipients to measure D
C
/N. However, because D
C
/N is an equilibrium quantity, we show in the
proposition below that the tuition effect is differentially larger for schools facing a higher s, i.e. the
fraction of low income students in the population served by the school.
Proposition 3. The larger the share of C students the higher the sensitivity of tuition to B.
s
t
B
=
δNω
( δN + D
C
ω)
2
D
C
s
> 0. (8)
The above proposition justifies our empirical approach of relating institutional exposures, cal-
culated as the share of students who are constrained by a particular policy maximum, to predicted
9
tuition increases in policy years. Given that our sample is composed of for-profit and not-for-profit
institutions, a natural question is to what extent the tuition effect depends on γ. It turns out that the
effect is ambiguous and depends on the difference between the quality of H and L students. This is
because, γ and the distribution of student quality interact in determining the share of low-income
students served by each institution.
8
In the empirical analysis, we study differential responses of
tuition increases to shifts in loan caps as a function of D
C
/N, and control for population quality
and γ by including institution fixed effects in the empirical model.
3 Federal Student Aid Programs
Federal student aid programs are governed by Title IV of the 1965 Higher Education Act (HEA)
and aim to support access to postsecondary education through the issuance of federal grants and
loans.
Pell Grants are the main source of federal grants, and are awarded to low-income (undergrad-
uate) students in financial need. Pell Grant disbursement averaged around $30 billion in recent
years, compared to an average of about $70 billion for federal student loan originations to under-
graduates (Figure 4).
The majority of federal student loans are administered under the William D. Ford Federal Di-
rect Loan (DL) Program
9
and come in two types: subsidized and unsubsidized. The exact terms
of federal loans have changed over time but typically involve low interest rates and flexible re-
payment plans. The federal government pays the interest on a subsidized student loan during
in-school status, grace periods, and authorized deferment periods. Qualification for subsidized
loans is based on financial need, while unsubsidized loans, where the student is responsible for
interest payments, are not. Together, these two programs make up about 85% of federal student
8
More precisely, we show in the appendix that
∂γ
t
B
< 0
D
H,C
D
C
<
δD
H,U
+ (δ + ω)D
H,C
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
(9)
9
Historically, these were also administered under the FFEL program and known as “Stafford loans. Under FFEL,
private lenders would originate loans to students that were then funded by private investors and guaranteed by the
federal government. Under the DL program, the ED directly originates loans to students, which are funded by Treasury.
With the Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010 the FFEL program was eliminated, but the types of loans
offered to students were not affected.
10
loan originations, with the rest coming from PLUS and Perkins loans.
10
Federal loans are the prin-
cipal form of student loans in the U.S., representing an even large share since the financial crisis
(Figure 3).
11
Eligibility. Federal student aid amounts are determined by individual maximums, which depend
on the particular education cost and family income of a student, and by overall program maximums
that apply to all students, which we use for identification.
Eligible students can qualify for federal loans and grants by filling out the Free Application
for Federal Student Aid (FAFSA). The primary output from the FAFSA is the student expected
family contribution (EFC), which represents the total educational costs that students and/or their
families are expected to contribute, which is computed as a function of family and student income
and savings, family size, and living expenses.
A student’s aid package is determined through a hierarchical process starting with need-based
aid, which includes Pell Grants and subsidized loans, as well as Federal Work Study and Federal
Perkins Loans (which are small). Need-based aid is capped at a student’s “financial need,” or the
portion of the cost of attendance (COA, the sum of tuition, room and board, and other costs or fees)
that is not covered by the EFC:
Pell Grants + Subsidized Loans Financial Need COA EFC, (10)
where the left-hand side omits, for simplicity, other (less-important) need based aid. Pell Grants are
subject to an additional EFC restriction, where only students with an EFC below a certain threshold
are eligible, with the maximum amount offered decreasing with EFC. This is in contrast to subsi-
dized loans, for which maximum amounts do not depend on EFC aside from (10). The hierarchical
aid assignment is such that students who are eligible for a Pell Grant will be offered it to cover their
10
PLUS loans require that borrowers do not have adverse credit histories and are awarded to graduate students and
parents of dependent undergraduate students. Finally, Perkins loans are made by specific participating institutions to
students who have exceptional financial need.
11
Federal loan programs do not require repayment when still in school, and do not require a credit record or cosigner.
Interest rates have varied and been both fixed and floating. Rates on all federal loans to undergraduates currently
stand at 4.29 percent. Loan repayment starts after a six-month grace period following school completion, and standard
repayment plans are ten years. Payments can be stopped for deferments (back to school) or forbearance (hardship).
Under “income based repayment” plans, borrowers can limit their loan payments to a fraction of their income.
11
financial need before any loan or other need-based aid.
Eligibility for non-need-based federal aid (which include Unsubsidized Loans and PLUS loans)
is determined by computing the portion of the COA that is not covered by federal need-based aid
or private aid (e.g. institutional grants):
Unsubsidized Loans + PLUS Loans COA Need-Based Aid Private Aid. (11)
Irrespective of the individual maximums, aid amounts are always capped by each program maxi-
mum. Unsubsidized borrowing can also occur in circumstances where a student’s financial need is
below the subsidized program maximum. Students can borrow up to their personal need in sub-
sidized loans and then borrow unsubsidized loans in an amount such that their joint subsidized
and unsubsidized borrowing is equal to the subsidized program maximum.
Changes in program maximums. Table 1 shows the evolution of federal aid program maximums
in our sample period. The subsidized maximum was raised in the 2007-2008 school year, unsub-
sidized loan maximums were raised in the 2008-2009 school year, and Pell Grant maximums were
raised and frozen through a series of appropriations and acts. In this section, we discuss the poli-
cies that changed these maximums and their impact on aggregate student loan originations.
The Higher Education Reconciliation Act (HERA) of 2006 increased the yearly borrowing caps
for subsidized loans, which had remained unchanged since 1992, for freshmen to $3,500 from
$2,625 and to $4,500 from $3,500 for sophomores. Borrowing limits for upperclassmen remained
unchanged at $5,500. Signed into law in February of 2006, the act took effect July 1, 2007, so that
the change was in place and well anticipated prior to the 2007-08 academic year. Though HERA
impacted borrowing for subsidized loans and unsubsidized loans (because, as described above,
the cap is technically a combined subsidized/unsubsidized borrowing cap), we expect this legis-
lation to mainly increase originations of subsidized loans, since if eligible, students would always
take out a subsidized over an unsubsidized loan. Thus, HERA would only affect unsubsidized
borrowing for freshman and sophomores that met two criteria; first, they did not have enough fi-
nancial need to qualify to take out the entire program maximum in subsidized loans, and second,
they chose to borrow the difference between the program maximum and their personal maximum
12
in the form of unsubsidized loans. These two joint conditions apply to less than one percent of
students in our sample, suggesting that unsubsidized borrowing was not significantly increased
in direct response to HERA. In comparison, roughly 22% of the freshman in our NPSAS sample
borrowed subsidized loans up to the program cap in 2004.
The data confirm that HERA primarily impacted subsidized borrowing. In the 2007-08 year,
subsidized loan originations to undergraduates jumped from $16.8 billion to $20.4 billion (Figure
3), and consistent with the higher usage intensity, the average size of a subsidized loan rose from
under $3,300 to $3,700, as shown in Figure 5, which reports average loan amounts per borrower.
Unsubsidized loan originations show much smaller increases in 2007-08, with the total amount
borrowed by undergraduates increasing from $13.6 to $14.7 billion, and the average per-borrower
amount increasing from $3,660 to $3,770. Because the majority of the impact of HERA was on subsi-
dized borrowing, we subsequently refer to HERA as affecting the subsidized borrowing maximum
to avoid confusion with legislation passed in subsequent years that primarily impacted unsubsi-
dized borrowing.
We provide additional evidence that these increases were due to the changes in the program
maximums using loan-level data from the New York Fed/Equifax Consumer Credit Panel.
12
This
data cannot distinguish between federal and private student loans, or subsidized and unsubsidized
loans, but in Figure 6, we produce a histogram of student loan amounts in the 2006-2007 school
year and again for the 2007-2008 school year, after the policy change. The “before” plot shows
a large mass of borrowers concentrated at the unconventional amount of $2,625, the subsidized
maximum for freshmen borrowers. In contrast, the “after” plot shows the largest mass of borrowers
concentrated at $3,500, the new maximum. The plots also show a large mass of borrowers at cap
amounts established for upperclassmen before and after the policy change. This shift is evidence
that there was a large and immediate effect of the policy change on loan amounts.
The second loan policy change we study is the Ensuring Continued Access to Student Loans
Act of 2008. Prior to this act, in addition to the subsidized amounts discussed above, independent
12
A number of papers have used this data to study loan repayments (see, for example, Lee, Van der Klaauw, Haugh-
wout, Brown, and Scally, 2014). We use this alternative source because NPSAS data is only available in the years 2004,
2008, and 2012, and is a repeated cross-section rather than a panel.
13
students were eligible for as much as $5,000 ($4,000 for freshman and sophomores) in additional
unsubsidized loans. Dependent students were ineligible for these additional loans.
13
This act
increased the maximums by $2,000 for all students, meaning dependent students were eligible for
$2,000. Figure 3 shows that undergraduate unsubsidized loan originations jumped from under $15
billion to $26 billion in one year. It is worth noting that the act was passed in anticipation of private
student loans becoming more difficult to obtain due to the financial crisis, and so some or all of
these new originations may have partly replaced private loans. Additionally, the act was passed
in May of 2008, after many financial aid packages had already been sent out for the academic year
2008-2009. Schools were told they could revise their offers to accommodate the new policies for
the upcoming school year, which seems to have been often the case based on the data series. That
said, due to the timing of the change, the full impact of the higher caps may have had real effects
in more than a single year.
While Pell Grants are not the main focus of this paper, Pell Grant maximums were adjusted
several times during our sample period, and are therefore included in our analysis. Maximums
rose gradually from $3,375 to $4,050 between 2001 and 2004 through the appropriation process.
They were then frozen at $4,050 for four years, until the Revised Continuing Appropriations Res-
olution of 2007 increased the maximum Pell Grant to $4,310 for the 2007-2008 school year, and the
College Cost Reduction and Access Act, passed by Congress on September 7, 2007 scheduled more
increases from $4,310 in 2007-2008 to $5,400 by the 2010-2011 school year. These maximums are
only available to students with an EFC below a certain threshold. However, students with slightly
higher EFCs are eligible for smaller Pell Grants, according to a scale. For all of the policy changes
we consider, these smaller Pell Grants increased proportionately with the maximum Pell Grant.
Pell Grant disbursements are plotted in Figure 4 against aggregate loan amounts; both show large
increases over our sample period.
Before turning to a systematic analysis of the effect of these policies on tuition, we provide
some direct evidence of the relevance of these policy changes to tuition at for-profit universities
13
Students must meet certain requirements (e.g. being over 24 years of age, being a graduate or professional stu-
dent, or being married) to be considered an independent student by the Federal Student Aid office; otherwise, they are
considered dependent and assumed to have parental support, and thus may qualify for less aid.
14
by looking at earnings call discussions between senior management at for-profit universities and
analysts around the time of the policy changes we study. Below, we quote from an earnings call
of one of the most prominent for-profit education companies, the Apollo Education Group (which
operates the University of Phoenix) in early 2007:
<Operator>: Your next question comes from the line of Jeff Silber with BMO Capital Markets.
<Q - Jeffrey Silber>: Close, it is Jeff Silber. I had a question about the increase in pricing at Axia; I’m just
curious why 10%, why not 5, and why not 15, what kind of market research went into that? And also if
you can give us a little bit more color potentially on some of the pricing changes we may see over the next
few months in some of the other programs?
<A - Brian Mueller>: The rationale for the price increase at Axia had to do with Title IV loan limit
increases. We raised it to a level we thought was acceptable in the short run knowing that we want to
leave some room for modest 2 to 3% increases in the next number of years. And so, it definitely was done
under the guise of what the student can afford to borrow. In terms of what we will do going forward with
regards to national pricing we’re keeping that pretty close to the vest. We will implement changes over
time and we will kind of alert you to them as we do it.
Source: Apollo Education Group, 2007:Q2 Earnings Call, accessed from Bloomberg LP.
As evidenced by this quote, Title IV loan limit increases appear to directly affect how this insti-
tution chose to set its tuition in those years, and we provide additional excerpts in Appendix C.
In Appendix D, we also show that the passage of the three pieces of student aid legislation were
associated with nearly 10% abnormal returns for the portfolio of all publicly traded for-profit insti-
tutions. This is consistent with the fact that changes in Title IV maximums had large implications
in terms of demand at these institutions. We turn to this issue in the rest of the paper using a
statistical model.
4 Data
We overview the data sources and sample used in the analysis and provide a more detailed
description of each of the data sources in Appendix E. We use data from three main sources from
the Department of Education: Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS), Title IV
Administrative Data from the Federal Student Aid Office, which we refer to as “Title IV” data, and
the restricted-use student-level National Postsecondary Student Aid Survey (NPSAS) dataset.
Our measures of sticker price and enrollment come from IPEDS. IPEDS is a system of surveys
15
conducted annually by the National Center for Education Statistics (NCES) with the purpose of
describing and analyzing trends in postsecondary education in the United States. All Title IV in-
stitutions are required to complete the IPEDS surveys. Though IPEDS began in 1980, the survey
covering sticker-price tuition was changed significantly in the 2000-2001 school year, and we thus
start our sample in this year.
We measure federal aid amounts at the institution level using the Title IV Program Volume
Reports, which report yearly institutional-level total dollar amounts and the number of recipients
for each federal loan and grant program. These data are available beginning with the 1999-2000
academic year separately for subsidized loans, unsubsidized loans, and Pell Grants.
14
We end
our sample in 2011-2012 to exclude the 2012-2013 school year and following years, when graduate
students became ineligible to receive subsidized loans as a result of the Budget Control Act of 2011,
which would complicate our measure of these loans.
Merging Title IV and IPEDS data, we obtain an annual panel of federal loan borrowing, Pell
Grants, enrollment and sticker-price tuition for the universe of Title IV institutions. This sample
contains 5,560 unique institutions. Institutional grant measures (graduate and undergraduate) are
available from the IPEDS Finance survey for 60% of our sample.
Finally, we supplement the IPEDS/Title IV panel with NPSAS, a restricted-use student-level
dataset from NCES. The primary purpose of the NPSAS data is to study student financing of higher
education and they thus have detailed information on the amount and type of loans that each
student takes out. NPSAS surveys have been conducted approximately every four years starting in
1988 with a nationally representative sample of about 100,000 students at a cross-section of Title IV
institutions. We mainly rely on the 2004 NPSAS to document pre-policy cross-sectional variation
that is only possible to observe with student-level data, since this data allows us to observe not just
institutional-level loan and grant totals, but the number of students who are constrained by each of
the policy maximums. The 2004 NPSAS contains this detailed financing data for students attending
14
Unfortunately, it does not separate loans given to undergraduates and loans given to graduate students until 2011
(Pell Grants are only given to undergraduates). However, because imputing the amount for undergraduates would
require making several assumptions, we measure loan and grant usage at an institution using the total dollar amount
scaled by the enrollment count (undergraduate and graduate, on a full-time-equivalent (FTE) basis) of the institution.
16
1,334 unique institutions, with an average (median) of 104 (85) students surveyed per institution.
15
Our final estimation sample is dictated by the merge of the Title IV/IPEDS data with NPSAS.
Depending on the specification, the number of institutions in the merged Title IV/IPEDS/NPSAS
sample ranges between 650, for specifications that require a measure of institutional grants, and
1,060, the number of institutions in our primary sticker tuition specification.
Table 2 reports summary statistics for the variables included in the regressions.
5 Empirical method
We present the difference-in-differences specification used to isolate the impact of the federal
loan credit expansion on tuition. Our empirical approach is similar to Card (1999), who studies
the effect of a change in national minimum wage standards using a cross-state treatment effect
based on the fraction of workers earning less than the minimum wage before the policy. In our
setting, we construct an institution-specific treatment intensity measure based on the fraction of
students in each institution that are eligible and that participate in the programs. We first discuss
the construction of the treatment intensity, or “policy exposures,” and then describe the empirical
specification.
Policy exposures. We use the student-level dataset NPSAS to define a narrow identification cri-
terion of the pre-policy importance of different types of aid at each institution. Consider first the
case of subsidized loans. If a student’s individual maximum is below the program maximum, she
cannot qualify for the program maximum and is thus unaffected by any changes to it. Additionally,
some students may choose to borrow less than the amount they are eligible for, and will thus also
be unaffected. We thus define an institution’s “exposure” to the subsidized loan policy change as
the fraction of undergraduate students who borrowed subsidized loans at the policy maximum in
2004, since this corresponds to approximately the fraction of students we would expect to be able
and willing to take advantage of the policy change to borrow more subsidized loans.
We also evaluate the effect of the 2008-2009 increase of $2,000 in additional unsubsidized loans
for all students. We separately calculate the exposures of dependent and independent students at
15
We also employ the 2008 NPSAS survey for robustness, which contains 1,697 unique institutions with an average
(median) of 111 (87) students surveyed per institution.
17
each institution, and take the sum as the overall institution exposure. For independent students,
we again take the fraction of students who were borrowing at the independent policy maximum
in 2004. For dependent students, who were previously ineligible for unsubsidized loans and be-
came eligible through the policy change, we construct a shadow participation rate since we cannot
observe past participation. This measure is the subset of eligible students, or the fraction of depen-
dent students at each institution, that borrowed the maximum amount of subsidized loans that
they were eligible for, including students who were not eligible for any subsidized loans.
16
The in-
tuition for this rule is that a student that could, but did not, borrow in the subsidized program will
not borrow in the unsubsidized program, as it is more expensive to do so, and should therefore
not be counted as a student constrained by the unsubsidized program cap. However, this measure
is likely not to be as reliable as the one for subsidized loans, since it assumes that any dependent
student borrowing the maximum amount of subsidized loans would also borrow the maximum
amount of unsubsidized loans once eligible.
Finally, for Pell Grants, changes in the maximum Pell Grant amounts shift the supply of grants
for all grant recipients. Thus, the Pell Grant exposure variable is calculated as the percent of stu-
dents at a given institution awarded any positive Pell Grant amount as of 2004. As we will see
below, because the policy shift applies to all amounts - -rather than just a certain threshold – Pell
Grant exposure displays a fairly high degree of correlation with EFCs, which also may complicate
identification.
Table 2 reports summary statistics for the exposure measures as of 2004. About 15% of all stu-
dents that borrowed were at the subsidized loan cap in 2004 compared to 27% of students at the
unsubsidized cap. In contrast, about 34% of students received a positive (not necessarily the max-
imum) amount of Pell Grants. The exposures also display significant variation, with a standard
deviation of between 14% (subsidized loans) and 21% (unsubsidized loans). The table also reports
summary statistics for the exposure variables computed from the 2008 NPSAS, for those institu-
tions that reported both in the 2004 (baseline sample) and in 2008 survey. Average levels of Pell
Grant and unsubsidized loan exposures are very similar in the two surveys, but the subsidized ex-
16
As discussed in Section 3, because subsidized loans are need-based, while unsubsidized loans are not, it is possible
to be eligible only for unsubsidized loans.
18
posure is significantly smaller, owing to the fact that the second NPSAS wave takes place after the
increase in the subsidized loan maximum. Indeed, as the maximums are increased, the fraction of
capped students should drop unless all students at the old maximum jump to the new maximums.
Empirical specification. We regress the date t yearly change in institution i characteristic Y
i t
Y
i t
=
a
β
a
ExpFedAid
ai
× CapFedAid
at
+ γX
i t
+ δ
i
+ φ
t
+ e
i t
, (12)
on a set of controls, where i denotes an institution, t is a year and a indicates either subsidized
loans, unsubsidized loans, or Pell Grants. In the main result, the dependent variable Y
i t
is changes
in sticker tuition. We also use changes in aid amounts as the dependent variable to validate the
treatment intensity, and in additional results, explore effects using changes in institutional grants
and enrollments as the dependent variable.
The main coefficient of interest is β
a
, which measures the sensitivity of tuition changes to
changes in the program maximums for each aid type a. The specification accomplishes this by
interacting the program cap change (CapFedAid
at
) with the institutional-level treatment inten-
sity measure described above (ExpFedAid
ai
). We estimate all three β
a
coefficients simultaneously
to control for correlations in exposures, timing of the policy changes and substitution effects. Our
regressions are specified in changes with institutional fixed effects δ
i
because there is wide disper-
sion across our sample in tuition charged (ranging from a few hundred dollars to about $45,000),
and tuition increases are often set as a percent of past tuition. Institutional fixed effects allow us
to control for the correlation of tuition increases with past tuition levels and look for abnormally
large increases at the institution level. We validate that this allows us to meet the parallel trends
assumption using placebo tests in Section 7. We include year effects to control for economy-wide
factors (e.g. increased demand for postsecondary education) that may have induced all institu-
tions to increase their tuition more in some years than others. Finally, we control for a set of other
controls X
i t
interacted with the policy changes as described in the results section.
An alternative coefficient of economic interest is the sensitivity of tuition to the equilibrium
institutional-level aid amounts. To obtain these, we consider an IV regression, where the first stage
uses equilibrium aid amounts as the dependent variable Y
i t
in (12) to construct an instrumented
19
change in each institution’s per-student federal aid,
d
FedAid. The second stage then regresses the
date t yearly change in each institution i variable of interest T
i t
T
i t
=
a
φ
a
d
FedAid
ait
+ γX
i t
+ δ
i
+ φ
t
+ e
i t
, (13)
on this instrument. As before, the regression includes institution and year fixed-effects and a set
of additional controls X
i t
. In contrast to the OLS estimates above, which measure the sensitivity of
tuition to relaxing the program maximums or caps, these IV estimates measure the sensitivity of
tuition to equilibrium changes in aid amounts, which are determined by the change in the caps as
well as the elasticity of aid demand. If there are high aid elasticities, we expect φ
a
and β
a
should
be very similar in magnitude. As discussed in Section 4, we measure financial aid levels with error
because, among other things, they include both undergraduate and graduate amounts. Thus we
focus mostly on the reduced form coefficient β
a
, which is also most immediately policy-relevant,
as opposed to the IV estimates of φ
a
in the results that follow.
6 Main empirical results
6.1 Sticker tuition and aid sensitivity to changes in program caps
Baseline specification. Table 3 presents our main results on aid and sticker tuition sensitivies to
the policy changes, measured as the product of the yearly change in each program cap (only varies
over time) and the treatment intensity based on the fraction of students at each institution that
qualify for (and are likely to accept) the increased student aid amounts. Each regression is esti-
mated between 2001-02 and 2011-12 and includes year and institution fixed effects, with standard
errors clustered at the institution level to account for serial correlation of the error terms.
Columns 1-3 validate our treatment measure by regressing yearly changes in student aid levels
on the product of treatment intensity and policy change. In columns 1 and 2, we find that yearly
changes in subsidized loans load on the institutional-level change in the loan maximum with a
coefficient of .7, while unsubsidized loans load with a coefficient of .57 on the unsubsidized maxi-
mum, suggesting that the demand elasticity for subsidized loans is quite high, and slightly lower
for unsubsidized loans. Both coefficients are different from zero and one at conventional levels. In
20
column 3, we find a coefficient for Pell Grants of 1.2, which is significantly different from zero at the
1% level but not different from one at conventional statistical levels, suggesting that an increase in
Pell Grant availability results in a one-for-one increase in the equilibrium grant amount disbursed,
i.e. that the demand elasticity for these grants is infinite, which is unsurprising.
17
It is also interesting to look at substitution across aid types: in column 3, we also observe that
the coefficients of Pell Grant usage on changes in unsubsidized and subsidized loan maximums are
close to zero, implying that a greater availability of these other sources do not displace Pell Grants.
On the other hand, in columns 1 and 2, the institution-level Pell Grant maximum change enters
each loan regression with a negative and statistically significant sign, suggesting that a greater
availability of Pell Grants displaces loan aid. This crowd-out effect may be the result of a lower
demand or reduced eligibility for loans as implied by equations (11) and (10) and is consistent
with Marx and Turner (2015) who find using a kink regression discontinuity design that increases
in Pell Grant aid lower student loan borrowing.
Having documented the large responses of federal aid amounts to our treatment variables, we
focus next on the response of sticker tuition to these treatments. Point estimates (column 4) sug-
gest that a dollar increase in the subsidized cap and unsubsidized caps result in a 58 cent increase
in sticker price (t-stat = 3.4), and 17 cent increase (t-stat = 4), respectively, and a dollar increase
in the Pell Grant maximum (column 6) translates into a 37 cent increase in sticker price (t-stat =
2.5). The estimates provide support to the Bennett Hypothesis, with an average passthrough of
increased student aid supply to tuition of around 40 cents on the dollar, although there is sub-
stantial heterogeneity across aid types. This is a large effect, and because it applies to sticker price
tuition, it is likely affecting both the recipients of these loans as well as other students who do not
borrow through the federal student loan program to fund their education. Although our focus
and model is on student loans, one may have expected the largest tuition sensitivity to be on Pell
Grants. While differences in passthroughs are not statistically significant, we note that changes in
caps for Pell Grants took place over a number of years, which may attenuate the magnitude of the
17
For brevity, the model in Section 2 abstracts from differences in interest and principal payment across types of aid.
But a straightforward extension would predict that the elasticity of Pell Grant demand should be infinite given that
grants are not subject to repayment.
21
point estimate.
IV specification. Thus far we have estimated the direct sensitivity of sticker tuition to changes in
the “treatment” of increased aid maximums. Because some previously constrained students may
not want to or be able to take advantage of the full cap increase, these changes do not necessarily
translate one-for-one into actual aid taken (as shown in the first three columns of Table 3). To study
how much tuition increases for each additional dollar of actual aid received we report in column
4 estimates for the second stage of the IV regression of tuition on aid amounts where each aid
measure is instrumented by the institution-specific measure of change in aid maximums. Changes
in sticker-price tuition have a coefficient of 89 cents on the dollar on the change in subsidized loan
amounts (t-stat = 2.5). The unsubsidized loan effect is smaller (t-stat = 2.5) and the Pell Grant
effect is estimated at 53 cents on the dollar (t-stat < 2.9). All of these estimates are similar to the
direct sensitivities of sticker tuition to the measure of institution-specific aid maximums because
the coefficients in the first stage are close to one.
6.2 Net tuition, institutional grants and enrollments
Net tuition and institutional grants Because many universities award institutional grants based
on need or merit, not all students pay the sticker tuition price for their education, and because
many of these grants are need-based, it is likely that many students who borrow in the federal
student loan program may not be paying sticker price. However, as discussed in Section 2, when
capacity is imperfectly elastic in the short run, aid to one group of students will create a pecuniary
demand externality that could impact the prices paid by non-aid recipients as well. The results
of our baseline regression show that non-recipients (in particular, students paying sticker-price
tuition) do indeed see price increases following an increase in loan supply. It is possible that uni-
versities increased sticker-price tuition while simultaneously increasing institutional grants and
so it was only sticker-price-paying students who were affected by these increases. We investigate
this question in this section and find that institutional grants do not completely cancel out the ef-
fect of price increases for these students; in fact, they tend to decrease alongside tuition increases,
meaning they may actually amplify the effect in our baseline regression.
We measure institutional grants using the IPEDS Finance Survey. Unfortunately, we note that
22
this is only available for 60% of our sample. As shown in Table 4, an increase in subsidized loans
is associated with a decline in institutional grants of about 20 cents on the dollar (t-stat = 1.7), un-
subsidized loans have a coefficient not significantly different from zero, and an expansion in Pell
Grants is associated with a reduction in institutional grants of 30 cents on the dollar (t-stat = 2).
The results for Pell Grants are consistent with Turner (2014), who, using a regression discontinu-
ity approach, finds that institutions alter institutional aid to capture increases in Pell Grants. In
column 2 we regress the difference in sticker price and institutional grants and find a sensitivity
with respect to subsidized loans of about .88 (t-stat = 3), to unsubsidized loans of about .15 (t-stat
= 2.2), and to Pell Grants of about .4 (t-stat = 1.6). Although only available for a subsample of the
original sample, these results suggest that the increase in federal aid resulted in increases in net
tuition similar to those in sticker tuition because of (at times) significant declines in institutional
grants.
Enrollments One of the main motivations for federal student aid is to relax participation con-
straints in postsecondary education, so understanding whether enrollment, in addition to price,
responds to changes in loan supply is crucial to assessing the welfare impact of these policies. In
fact, we show in Section 2 that imperfect supply elasticity guarantees that there will be price ef-
fects to some degree, but it is interesting to measure to what degree enrollment effects are also
present. To evaluate enrollment effects we regress annual changes in enrollment on our measures
of treatment intensity interacted with the timing of policy changes. As shown in column 3 of
Table 4, we find a positive and statistically significant coefficient on institution-specific changes
in caps for Pell Grants, but an insignificant coefficient on subsidized loan caps and a significant
but tiny negative coefficient on unsubsidized loan caps. The point estimate on Pell Grants is eco-
nomically significant – for example the 2010 increase in Pell amounts at the mean Pell exposure
(( 5350 4731) × .34 = 210) would have implied a boost in enrollment of about 3.5% – and is also
consistent with the literature on grants and college participation (see for example the review of
Deming and Dynarski (2009)).
18
The relative ordering of these effects is consistent with economic
18
They conclude that most studies of federal aid find that additional grant aid is associated with significant increases
in attendance (e.g. Seftor and Turner (2002) for Pell Grants; Angrist (1993), Stanley (2003), Bound and Turner (2002) for
GI Bills; Dynarski (2003) for Social Security student benefit program), though, for Pell Grants the evidence is mixed,
as (Hansen (1983) and Kane (1995) find no significant increase in attendance following the introduction of Pell Grants).
23
priors, since, as previously noted, demand elasticities are largest for Pell Grants because the prin-
cipal does not have to be repaid. In addition, these results suggest, as we assumed in Section 2,
that the enrollment effects of increased loan supply may be small in the short-run.
7 Additional empirical results
We first discuss the robustness of the empirical findings from the previous section. We then at-
tempt to identify the set of institutions for which the passthrough from aid to tuition was strongest
and focus on for-profit institutions, which are under-represented in main sample.
7.1 Robustness of baseline specification
We attempt to address two potential concerns about the estimated effects of the student credit
expansion on tuition. The first is measurement issues related to the Great Recession and other
shocks to institution funding. A second main concern is that treated and control groups differ
along important dimensions which more generally affect their tuition levels even in the absence
of the changes in student aid maximums. We address this latter concern by studying the parallel
trends assumption and by interacting policy changes with other institution-characteristics.
Excluding the Great Recession Policy changes for the loan programs went into effect in the 2007-
08 (subsidized loan limit) and 2008-09 (additional unsubsidized loan limits) academic years. One
may be concerned about the impact of the Great Recession on tuition in these years. On the demand
side, a high unemployment rate may have boosted demand for education services at institutions
with a student population that is more dependent on student aid. On the supply side, these same
institutions may have experienced a drop in state appropriations or endowments. Both of these
effects could have led to disproportionate tuition increases. However, it is important to note that
tuition decisions each academic year are generally made in the first half of each calendar year.
This means that the increase in the subsidized loan maximum predates the recession, as tuition
for the 2007-2008 academic year would have been set in the spring of 2007. The unsubsidized loan
policy comes into effect before the failure of Lehman Brothers, but after the start of the recession. In
Table 5, we present estimates of the baseline tuition specification for tuition (repeated in column 1),
Many fewer studies look at federal loan aid; one exception is Dynarski (2002) who finds a very small effect on attendance
and a larger effect on college choice.
24
but only including data up to the 2008-09 and 2007-08 academic years. We find that the subsidized
loan effect is unaffected by the shorter samples, and that the unsubsidized loan effect is robust to
excluding years beginning with the 2009-10 school year (excluding 2008-2009 would exclude the
main policy change).
Additional controls Our second robustness check adds a set of controls X
i t
to the baseline speci-
fication (12). Anecdotal evidence suggests that for-profit universities (e.g. those quoted in Section
3) may be more likely to take advantage of credit expansions as opportunities to raise tuition. Per-
sistent differences in tuition increases between for-profit and not-for-profit universities would be
captured by the institutional fixed effects in our baseline specification, but to allow for differential
responses in the years of the policy changes we include an interaction between for-profit status and
each of the the three changes in the program caps: hPGCap
t
, SLCap
t
, USLCap
t
i. The inclu-
sion of these controls does not appear to significantly change the point estimates on the measures
of institution-specific program caps (column 1 in Table 6) relative to the baseline (column 4 in Ta-
ble 3).
The second column of Table 6 applies the same logic above to several other dimensions of het-
erogeneity that may differentially affect tuition and aid: namely, the type of degree(s) offered, (Fig-
ure 8), how selective and expensive they are, and the average income of the students enrolled. For
example, if community colleges offering 2-year degrees experienced a boost in demand, and con-
sequently increased tuition amid the high unemployment levels experienced during the Great Re-
cession, this could potentially bias our coefficients. Once again, to the extent that these institutional
characteristics affected tuition across all years, their effect would be absorbed by the institutional
fixed effects that we include in the regressions. We thus interact a 4-year program dummy, the ad-
mission rate, average EFC, and average level of tuition (all measured in 2004) with the changes in
the program caps. As shown in column 2 of Table 6, which includes these additional 18 controls,
while the coefficient on the subsidized loan cap is largely unaffected both in magnitude and its
significance, those on Pell Grants and especially the one on unsubsidized loans drop in magnitude
and become insignificant.
We note that for Pell Grants in particular, the controls above absorb much of the variation of
25
our treatment intensity measure, and thus it is unsurprising that our estimated treatment effect
decreases subtantially. In Table 7, we report the correlation between the intensity measures with
EFC and tuition and find that EFC is highly correlated with the Pell Grant exposure but displays
low to moderate levels of correlation with unsubsidized and subsidized loans. This is because the
exposure to Pell Grants is based on the fraction of students receiving any positive grant amount
(which is highly correlated with institution’s mean student income levels) while loan exposures are
only based on students at caps (which depend on a specific percentile of the income distribution).
The final column of Table 6 controls for changes in other sources of funding that could be af-
fecting tuition. As discussed in detail in Appendix B, universities fund their operations both from
tuition revenue, and from other sources such as government appropriations and other sources,
including private donations. Much discussion has been devoted to this topic (see, for example,
Congressional Research Service, 2014) particularly in the context of changes in state funding and
private contributions. We thus supplement the specification of column 1 with the 2-year change
in these sources of institution revenue (to account for possible delays between the time in which
these other sources of funding are known to administrators) as controls.
19
We find that declines
in state and private funding are associated with increases in tuition. In this specification the Pell
Grant coefficient again loses significance, while the coefficient on subsidized loans is unaffected.
The coefficient on unsubsidized loans is lower in magnitude but remains marginally significant.
Placebo analysis In the baseline model (equation 12), we identified tuition and aid sensitivities
from the regression coefficients β
a
, on each interaction measure of institution-level program max-
imum changes. To see if more and less exposed institutions experienced similar tuition and aid
trends in the years when caps were not raised, we follow e.g. Autor (2003), and analyze how the
β
a
s would have been estimated had we (as a placebo) analyzed cross-sectional differences in tuition
and aid in years where no actual policy occurred. For each aid of type a we estimate the following:
Y
i t
=
s
ξ
as
ExpFedAid
ai
× 1(year = s) +
α6=a
β
α
ExpFedAid
αi
× CapFedAid
αt
+ γX
i t
+ δ
i
+ φ
t
+ e
i t
.
(14)
19
This data is only available for a somewhat smaller sample (8,000 observations versus 10,500 in the baseline).
26
Here we control for the other aid types (α) that are not subject to a placebo by interacting them
with the corresponding actual changes in program caps as in the baseline specification (12). For
aid a, instead, we estimate a series of yearly cross-sectional regressions of changes in tuition and
aid on their exposures to aid. The coefficients ξ
as
identify, in each year, abnormal changes in the
dependent variables relative to the omitted or baseline year. We set the baseline year to be 2006,
which is when the first of three major legislative acts affecting program caps was passed.
For each type of aid, time series estimates for ξ
as
are shown as the orange lines in the top, mid-
dle and bottom panels of Figure 7. We also plot 95% pointwise confidence intervals, and include
gray bars indicating the actual changes in each program maximum weighted by the average cross-
sectional exposures (measured on 2004 NPSAS) for each aid type. For comparability, scales are
set equal across all charts. For subsidized loans, the loading on subsidized exposure ξ
as
of subsi-
dized loan amounts (panel a) and tuition (panel b) spike coincident to the changes in subsidized
maximums (gray bar) and are both significant at the 5% levels. For sticker-price tuition we indeed
observe the largest spike in 2007-08, but also observe higher sensitivity in 2006-07 and 2008-09,
which may be consistent with some sluggish tuition adjustment or anticipatory effects from an-
nouncement to implementation of these policies.
For unsubsidized loans we observe a very similar pattern with respect to loan amounts (panel
c) with spikes on the loadings on exposure that are coincident to the policy changes (2007-08 and
especially 2008-09). Tuition’s loading on unsubsidized exposure (panel d) displays higher than
average levels in 2006-07 and 2008-09, but only the 2008-09 change is significant. While it may be
initially surprising that we do not observe a 2007-08 tuition increase, we note that because that
policy affected both subsidized and unsubsidized loans and we control for the actual change in
subsidized loans in our placebo regression, we have made it much more difficult to find this effect
than in our baseline regression.
The bottom two panels show parameter estimates for Pell Grants. Policy changes for Pell Grants
are much more gradual and take place in multiple years. In those years, the cross-sectional ex-
pansion in Pell amounts are significantly related to the institution exposures (significant at 5%) in
contrast to the changes in sticker prices, which are not statistically larger in those years. In sum, the
27
placebo tests confirm that NPSAS exposures are valid sorting variables for aid amounts. In terms
of tuition, we find that cross-sectional differences in tuition changes with respect to aid exposures
are coincident for subsidized and (to a lesser extent) for unsubsidized loan amounts, but not for
Pell Grants.
In Appendix F, we show additional robustness checks where we measure exposures from the
2008 NPSAS wave rather than the 2004 wave, and where we specify the dependent variables in
logarithm changes rather than level changes. In sum, we find a robust passthrough of federal aid
to tuition in the form of subsidized loans and a weaker effect of unsubsidized loans and Pell Grants.
For unsubsidized loans in particular, this weakness may be due to limitations to our identification
approach, since, as we have discussed in Section 5, the exposures are more difficult to measure,
and the policy change coincided with the contraction in the private student loan market and the
Great Recession. It is also quite possible that subsidized loans, which represent a more significant
subsidy than unsubsidized loans and are awarded to less needy students than Pell Grants, are in
fact more economically meaningful in tuition-setting decisions. We believe the results we present
on subsidized loans are new to the literature. We find a sensitivity of changes in tuition to changes
in subsidized loan amounts on the order of about 40-60 cents on the dollar, with estimates that are
highly significant in essentially all of the specifications considered.
7.2 Attributes of tuition-increasing institutions and the for-profit sector
Attributes of tuition-increasing institutions Results presented thus far indicate that changes in
the sticker price of tuition are, on average, sensitive to changes in the supply of subsidized loans,
Pell Grants, and unsubsidized loans, with a particularly robust subsidized loan effect. In this sec-
tion we dig deeper into these results to characterize the attributes of institutions that displayed
the largest passthrough effects of aid on tuition. For each form of aid, we interact in Table 8 the
measure of institution-level exposure with key cross-sectional characteristics: whether a program
offers four-year degrees, whether the school is a private institution, the tuition level in 2004, and
the average EFC of the student population in 2004.
20
20
As the model of Section 2 points out in the context of γ, these interaction effects can be complex and non-linear.
Because here we are estimating linear models, estimates are only picking up average effects.
28
In terms of changes in subsidized loan caps (column 1), we find that private institutions and
non-four-year institutions (community colleges or vocational institutions) have larger average sen-
sitivities, as did those that charged higher tuition (all results significant at 1% level). In addition,
institutions with students having lower EFCs also displayed a higher sensitivity although the dif-
ference is not significant at conventional levels (t-stat = 1.5). Results for changes in the unsubsidized
loan caps (column 2) are similar but are weaker in magnitude – only the tuition level difference is
significant at conventional levels. Finally none of the interactions between the institution char-
acteristics and the institution-level measures of changes in Pell Grant maximums are significant,
suggesting homogeneous effects among institutions in our sample.
In conclusion, we find that expensive, private, or sub-four-year programs are associated with
larger tuition responses to loan maximum changes, while responses to Pell Grants displayed a more
uniform response across institutions.
Evidence for the for-profit sector Since the 1972 HEA re-authorization allowed for-profit insti-
tutions to be eligible to receive federal student aid, the market share of for-profit institutions has
grown substantially (Deming, Goldin, and Katz, 2012). For-profit institutions now receive over
76.7% of their revenue, on average, through Title IV programs. This heavy dependence on federal
aid has led to increased regulation and concern. Our data contains limited information on these
institutions (less than 10% of institutions in NPSAS04). We presented some anecdotal evidence
that for-profit institutions react to federal aid changes using earnings call discussions and stock
market responses in Section 5. In Table 9, we provide additional evidence on the differential effect
of these increases on for-profit institutions by comparing changes in aid amounts at for-profit (top
panel) and other institutions (bottom panel) in our sample period. For each type of institution (and
panel) we regress yearly changes on year dummy variables (reported at the top of each panel and
with the year 2006, which is the year preceding the policy changes, serving as the omitted year) as
well as on a policy year dummy variable which is equal to one for the 2007-08, 2008-09 and 2009-
10 academic years when the federal aid changes went into effect (reported at the bottom of each
panel). As shown in the bottom section of the panels, for-profit institutions experienced signifi-
cantly larger increases in disbursed aid over the years of the aid cap changes. Correspondingly,
29
these institutions also displayed sticker tuition increases of about $212, on average, as compared to
$56 for not-for-profit institutions. These larger tuition increases are consistent with the results in
the paper and the heavy reliance of for-profit institutions on federal student aid. This raw compar-
ison has obvious limitations; for example, it does not allow us to control for other events specific
to the for-profit sector that may have affected tuition. However, given the recent policy initiatives
directly targeting aid for students attending for-profit institutions, a better understanding of the
role of student borrowing for these institutions remains an open and important issue.
8 Concluding remarks
We studied the effects of a student credit expansion on tuition costs using a difference-in-
differences approach around changes in federal loan program maximums to undergraduate stu-
dents in the academic years 2007-08 and 2008-09. Consistent with the prediction of the illustra-
tive model, institutions that were most exposed to these program maximums ahead of the policy
changes experienced disproportionate tuition increases. We estimate tuition effects of changes in
institution-specific program maximums of about 60 cents on the dollar for subsidized loans and
15 cents on the dollar for unsubsidized loans. The subsidized loan effects are robust to placebo
tests and the inclusion of a large number of additional controls. Consistent with the model, we
find that even when universities price-discriminate, a credit expansion will raise tuition paid by
all students and not only by those at the federal loan caps because of pecuniary demand exter-
nalities. Such pricing externalities are often conjectured in the context of the effects of expanded
subprime borrowing on housing prices leading up to the financial crisis, and our study can be seen
as complementary evidence in the student loan market.
It is also important to note that while tuition increased steadily over our full sample period,
the policy changes we exploit were concentrated in a few years later in the sample. This does
not rule out a role of student credit in the observed tuition trends that is independent of policy
changes. Previous work, for example, shows that greater aid availability tends to raise tuition
levels more generally (Cellini and Goldin, 2014). In unreported results, we analyze pre-policy
trends in aid and tuition. We find a positive association between ex-ante aid dependence (as of
2001-02), and subsequent aid growth in the pre-policy period. In terms of tuition, we observe a
30
positive association with loan dependence for low initial aid levels consistent with binding credit
constraints.
So do federal student loan programs represent bad policy? Importantly we also find a positive
association between aid-dependence and subsequent enrollment expansion. This is in contrast to
limited enrollment effects around changes in program maximums, likely owing to the differential
elasticity of supply in the short- and medium-run. Expansion in enrollment means increased access
to post-secondary education, which is particularly important given the positive gap between the
cost of education and its social or private benefit.
21
Judging the welfare implications of federal
student loan programs ultimately needs to weigh tuition effects and increased participation.
21
While the literature disagrees on the exact magnitude of the returns to higher education (Card, 1999; Avery and
Turner, 2012), the “college wage-premium” has been shown to be rising over the past two decades due to demand
for skilled workers outpacing supply, and contributing to growing wage inequality in the US (Goldin and Katz, 2009).
Given this premium, to the extent that greater access to credit increases access to postsecondary education, student aid
programs may help lower wage inequality by boosting the supply of skilled workers.
31
References
Adelino, M., A. Schoar, and F. Severino (2012). Credit supply and house prices: evidence from
mortgage market segmentation. Technical report, NBER.
Angrist, J. D. (1993). The effect of veterans benefits on education and earnings. Industrial & labor
relations review 46(4), 637–652.
Autor, D. H. (2003). Outsourcing at will: The contribution of unjust dismissal doctrine to the
growth of employment outsourcing. Journal of labor economics 21(1), 1–42.
Avery, C. and S. Turner (2012). Student loans: Do college students borrow too much?or not enough?
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 165–192.
Bennett, W. J. (1987). Our greedy colleges. New York Times 18, A27.
Bound, J. and S. Turner (2002). Going to war and going to college: Did world war ii and the gi bill
increase educational attainment for returning veterans? Journal of Labor Economics 20(4), 784–815.
Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. Handbook of labor economics 3, 1801–1863.
Cellini, S. R. and C. Goldin (2014). Does federal student aid raise tuition? new evidence on for-
profit colleges. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6(4), 174–206.
Congressional Research Service (2014). Overview of the relationship between federal student aid
and increases in college prices. Technical Report R43692.
Deming, D. and S. Dynarski (2009). Into college, out of poverty? policies to increase the postsec-
ondary attainment of the poor. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Deming, D. J., C. Goldin, and L. F. Katz (2012). The for-profit postsecondary school sector: Nimble
critters or agile predators? Journal of Economic Perspectives 26(1), 139–64.
Dynarski, S. (2002). Loans, liquidity, and schooling decisions. Kennedy School of Government Working
Paper.
Dynarski, S. (2003). Does aid matter? measuring the effect of student aid on college attendance
and completion. The American Economic Review.
Epple, D., R. Romano, S. Sarpc¸a, and H. Sieg (2013). The us market for higher education: A general
equilibrium analysis of state and private colleges and public funding policies. Technical report,
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Epple, D., R. Romano, and H. Sieg (2006). Admission, tuition, and financial aid policies in the
market for higher education. Econometrica 74(4), 885–928.
Favara, G. and J. Imbs (2015). Credit supply and the price of housing. American Economic Re-
view 105(3), 958–92.
32
Goldin, C. D. and L. F. Katz (2009). The race between education and technology. Harvard University
Press.
Gordon, G. and A. Hedlund (2016, February). Accounting for the rise in college tuition. Working
Paper 21967, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Government Accountability Office (2010). Institutions’ reported data collection burden is higher
than estimated but can be reduced through increased coordination. Technical report.
Hansen, W. L. (1983). Impact of student financial aid on access. Proceedings of the Academy of Political
Science, 84–96.
Kane, T. J. (1995). Rising public college tuition and college entry: How well do public subsidies
promote access to college? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Kotlikoff, L. J. and L. H. Summers (1987). Chapter 16 tax incidence. In A. J. Auerbach and M. Feld-
stein (Eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 2 of Handbook of Public Economics, pp. 1043 –
1092. Elsevier.
Lee, D., W. Van der Klaauw, A. Haughwout, M. Brown, and J. Scally (2014). Measuring student
debt and its performance. FRB of New York Staff Report (668).
Long, B. T. (2004a). How do financial aid policies affect colleges? the institutional impact of the
georgia hope scholarship. Journal of Human Resources 39(4), 1045–1066.
Long, B. T. (2004b). The impact of federal tax credits for higher education expenses. In College
choices: The economics of where to go, when to go, and how to pay for it, pp. 101–168. University of
Chicago Press.
Marx, B. M. and L. J. Turner (2015). Borrowing trouble? student loans, the cost of borrowing, and
implications for the effectiveness of need-based grant aid. Technical report, National Bureau of
Economic Research.
McPherson, M. S. and M. O. Schapiro (1991). Keeping college affordable: Government and educational
opportunity. Brookings Institution Press.
Mian, A. and A. Sufi (2009). The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: Evidence from the
u.s. mortgage default crisis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4), 1449–1496.
Rizzo, M. J. and R. G. Ehrenberg (2003, February). Resident and nonresident tuition and enrollment
at flagship state universities. Working Paper 9516, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Seftor, N. S. and S. E. Turner (2002). Back to school: Federal student aid policy and adult college
enrollment. Journal of Human Resources, 336–352.
Singell, L. D. and J. A. Stone (2007). For whom the pell tolls: The response of university tuition to
federal grants-in-aid. Economics of Education Review 26(3), 285–295.
33
Stanley, M. (2003). College education and the midcentury gi bills. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
671–708.
Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. MIT press.
Turner, L. J. (2014). The road to pell is paved with good intentions: The economic incidence of
need-based student aid. Technical report, Working paper.
34
Figure 1: Sticker Tuition and Per-student Federal Student Loans This figure plots average under-
graduate sticker-price tuition and average federal student loan amounts per full-time-equivalent
student. Amounts shown are in 2012 dollars. Source: IPEDS/Title IV.
0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000
Dollars
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Sticker Price Tuition Subsidized Loan
Unsubsidized Loan Other Federal Loans
35
Figure 2: Non-mortgage-related Household Debt Balances This figure shows the time-series evo-
lution of non-mortgage-related debt balances. Amounts shown are in nominal terms. Source: NY
Fed CCP/Equifax.
200 400 600 800 1000 1200
Dollars, billions
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Student loans Credit cards
Auto loans HELOCs
36
Figure 3: Aggregate Student Loan Originations This figure shows the time-series evolution of ag-
gregate student loan originations by program type. Amounts shown are in nominal terms. Source:
College Board.
0 50 100 150
Dollars, billions
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Federal undergrad subsidized Federal undergrad unsubsidized
Federal undergrad PLUS Federal graduate (all)
Non-federal
37
Figure 4: Aggregate Pell Grant and Federal Loan Amounts This figure plots Pell Grant disburse-
ments by year as compared to total undergraduate federal student loan originations. Source: Title
IV.
0 20 40 60 80
Dollars, billions
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Federal Student Loans (undergraduates only) Pell Grants
Figure 5: Per-borrower Subsidized and Unsubsidized Federal Student Loan Amounts This fig-
ure shows changes in the average borrowed amounts in the subsidized and unsubsidized loan
programs. Source: IPEDS, Title IV.
3000 3500 4000 4500
Dollars
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Subsidized Unsubsidized
38
Figure 6: Distribution of Student Loan Amounts These figures plot the distribution of student
loan amounts in the NY Fed CCP/Equifax panel in the year before (2006:Q3-2007:Q2) and after
(2007:Q3-2008:Q2) the change in the subsidized loan maximum. The maximums are marked on
the x-axis for each academic year. Source: NY Fed CCP/Equifax.
(a) Student Loan Amount in 2006-2007
0
5.0e+04
1.0e+05
1.5e+05
2.0e+05
Frequency
0 2625 3500 5500
(b) Student Loan Amount in 2007-2008
0
5.0e+04
1.0e+05
1.5e+05
Frequency
0 3500 4500 5500
39
Figure 7: Placebo tests This figure shows a time series (orange) of estimated ξ coefficients
from equation (14) measuring the sensitivity of Aid and Tuition to an institution expo-
sure to each type of aid. Vertical dotted black line (year 2006) is the baseline/omitted year
in the regression. Dotted blue lines represent 95% confidence intervals. For each aid type,
the gray bars show the actual mean change in program maximums, measured as the mean
of yearly cap changes times institution exposures.
(a) Subsidized loan exposure: Subsidized loans
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
(b) Subsidized loan exposure: Tuition
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
(c) Unsubsidized loan exposure: Unsubsidized loans
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
(d) Unsubsidized loan exposure: Tuition
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
(e) Pell Grant exposure: Pell Grants
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
(f) Pell Grant exposure: Tuition
-.5
0
.5
1
ξ
-250
0
250
500
Mean exposure X Δ policy cap (dollars)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Δ policy cap Estimated coefficient ξ
40
Table 1: Changes in Title IV Federal Aid Program Maximums This table shows changes to the
maximums (caps) (reported as dollar amounts) of the Federal Direct Loan and Pell Grant Program.
Y1, Y2, Y3, Y4, Grad are respectively the maximums for undergraduate freshmen, sophomores,
juniors, seniors and graduate students. (D) and (I) refers to dependent and independent students.
See Section 3 for more detail. Source: Higher Education Act, subsequent amendments and ED
appropriations.
Subsidized Loans Unsubsidized Loans Pell Grants
Year Y1 Y2 Y3/Y4 Grad Y1-Y4(D) Y1/Y2(I) Y3/Y4(I) Grad Y1-Y4
2000-01 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 3350
2001-02 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 3750
2002-03 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 4000
2003-04 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 4050
2004-05 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 4050
2005-06 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 4050
2006-07 2625 3500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 10000 4050
2007-08 3500 4500 5500 8500 0 4000 5000 12000 4310
2008-09 3500 4500 5500 8500 2000 6000 7000 12000 4731
2009-10 3500 4500 5500 8500 2000 6000 7000 12000 5350
2010-11 3500 4500 5500 8500 2000 6000 7000 12000 5550
2011-12 3500 4500 5500 8500 2000 6000 7000 12000 5550
41
Table 2: Summary statistics This table reports summary statistics for the variables included in the
regression tables. The unit of observation is a year (t) and institution (i). The sample starts in 2002
and ends in 2012. The operator indicates annual changes (between year t and t 1). Sample
sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Additional
detail on the variables are available in Section 4 and Appendix E.
Mean St.Dev. Min Max Count
StickerTuition
it
743.97 730.09 -2832.00 4256.00 10560
PellGrants
it
109.60 254.49 -1691.52 2144.92 10060
SubLoans
it
83.68 267.29 -1781.18 1908.91 9780
UnsubLoans
it
148.30 431.71 -3060.49 3410.32 9740
SubLoanExp
i
0.15 0.14 0.00 0.74 10560
UnsubLoanExp
i
0.27 0.21 0.00 1.00 10560
PellGrantExp
i
0.34 0.19 0.00 1.00 10560
SubLoanExp08
i
0.08 0.08 0.00 0.60 6640
UnsubLoanExp08
i
0.27 0.18 0.00 0.83 6640
PellGrantExp08
i
0.38 0.15 0.00 0.97 6640
InstGrant
it
268.56 451.99 -1672.54 2249.36 5570
StickerTuition
it
InstGrant
it
687.19 692.33 -3478.73 4892.03 5570
100 × log(FTE
it
) 2.30 9.26 -47.99 53.48 9630
2
StateFunding
it
11.68 1012.93 -4765.55 4795.79 9420
2
FederalFunding
it
93.46 588.62 -3147.55 3346.77 9340
2
OtherFunding
it
260.32 1384.37 -7436.50 8131.24 9340
2
PrivateFunding
it
79.62 4348.30 -25832.35 26098.26 9340
42
Table 3: Baseline regression specification The first four columns in this table report OLS regres-
sion estimates of yearly changes in Pell Grants and subsidized/unsubsidized loan amounts per
full-time equivalent student, and sticker tuition on interactions between cross-sectional institution
exposures and yearly changes in program caps. The last column reports IV regression estimates of
the effect of changes in federal loans and grants on sticker price tuition. The dependent variable
is the annual change in sticker price tuition at the institution level. Observed changes in federal
grants and loans per enrolled student are instrumented by the products of the corresponding aid
exposures and changes in program caps, as described in the text. The unit of observation is a year
(t) and institution (i). The sample starts in 2002 and ends in 2012. Sample sizes are rounded to
the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard errors clustered at the
institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
PellGrants
it
StickerTuition
it
StickerTuition
it
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
0.664
∗∗
0.146 0.056 0.587
∗∗
[0.12] [0.15] [0.07] [0.17]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
0.041
0.544
∗∗
-0.039
∗∗
0.168
∗∗
[0.02] [0.05] [0.01] [0.04]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
-0.389
∗∗
-0.482
∗∗
1.152
∗∗
0.373
∗∗
[0.08] [0.12] [0.09] [0.15]
SubLoans
it
0.891
∗∗
[0.35]
UnsubLoans
it
0.243
∗∗
[0.10]
PellGrants
it
0.527
∗∗
[0.18]
Estimator OLS OLS OLS OLS IV
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
.07 .21 .44 .38 .
N Obs 9790 9740 10060 10570 9320
N Inst 990 990 1040 1060 970
43
Table 4: Regression estimates for institutional grants and enrollments This table reports OLS
regression estimates of yearly changes in institution grant expenditure per FTE, difference between
sticker price and institution grant expenditure and percentage growth rate of FTE on interactions
between cross-sectional institution exposures and yearly changes in program caps. The unit of
observation is a year (t) and institution (i). The sample starts in 2002 and ends in 2012. Sample
sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard
errors clustered at the institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3)
InstGrant
it
StickerTuition
it
InstGrant
it
100 × log(FTE
it
)
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
-0.201
0.886
∗∗
-0.004
[0.12] [0.31] [0.00]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
-0.037 0.154
∗∗
-0.002
∗∗
[0.05] [0.07] [0.00]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
-0.330
∗∗
0.423 0.017
∗∗
[0.16] [0.28] [0.00]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
0.31 0.17 0.08
N Obs 6290 5580 11050
N Inst 690 650 1000
Table 5: Subsamples for baseline tuition regression specification This table reports OLS regres-
sion estimates of yearly changes in sticker tuition on interactions between cross-sectional institution
exposures and yearly changes in program caps. The unit of observation is a year (t) and institution
(i). Column 1 reproduces column 4 in Table 3 and is estimated between 2002 and 2012. The other
two columns restrict the estimation sample as noted. Sample sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in
compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard errors clustered at the institution level
reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3)
StickerTuition
it
Full sample Pre-2009 Pre-2008
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
0.587
∗∗
0.479
∗∗
0.502
∗∗
[0.17] [0.18] [0.18]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
0.168
∗∗
0.165
∗∗
-0.132
[0.04] [0.05] [0.31]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
0.373
∗∗
0.396
0.570
∗∗
[0.15] [0.21] [0.24]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
0.38 0.40 0.38
N Obs 10570 7720 6730
N Inst 1060 1050 1050
44
Table 6: Regression estimates with additional controls This table reports OLS estimates of the
baseline model (Table 3) with the inclusion of additional controls. The additional cross-sectional
controls (for which coefficients are not reported) are each interacted with the three changes in
program caps Caps
t
= hPGCap
t
, SLCap
t
, USLCap
t
i. Changes in other sources or funding
are computed over a two year period (
2
). The unit of observation is a year (t) and institution
(i). The sample starts in 2002 and ends in 2012. Sample sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in
compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard errors clustered at the institution level
reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3)
StickerTuition
it
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
0.584
∗∗
0.470
∗∗
0.452
∗∗
[0.18] [0.21] [0.20]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
0.165
∗∗
0.004 0.093
∗∗
[0.04] [0.06] [0.05]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
0.335
∗∗
0.176 0.119
[0.16] [0.24] [0.17]
2
StateFunding
it
-0.049
∗∗
[0.01]
2
FederalFunding
it
-0.005
[0.01]
2
OtherFunding
it
0.001
[0.01]
2
PrivateFunding
it
-0.004
∗∗
[0.00]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes
ForProfit
i
× Caps
t
Yes Yes Yes
Four-year
i
× Caps
t
No Yes No
AdmitRate04
i
× Caps
t
No Yes No
EFC04
i
× Caps
t
No Yes No
Tuition04
i
× Caps
t
No Yes No
Adj R
2
0.38 0.38 0.37
N Obs 10570 10480 8790
N Inst 1060 1040 950
Table 7: Correlation among institution characteristics This table reports a correlation matrix be-
tween institution level characteristics measured as of 2004. Standard errors clustered at the insti-
tution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
SubLoanExp
i
UnsubLoanExp
i
PellGrantExp
i
EFC
i
Tuition
i
AdmitRate
i
SubLoanExp
i
1
UnsubLoanExp
i
0.782 1
PellGrantExp
i
0.197 -0.0411 1
EFC
i
-0.0445 0.218 -0.731 1
Tuition
i
0.273 0.500 -0.395 0.660 1
AdmitRate
i
-0.145 -0.322 0.255 -0.424 -0.591 1
45
Table 8: Sensitivity of aid exposures to institution attributes This table expands on the base-
line results of Table 3 by allowing the coefficients to vary across these institution characteristics: a
dummy for private institutions, a dummy for 4-year programs, the 2004 levels of tuition and aver-
age EFC (both in thousands). See notes to Table 3 for more details. Sample sizes are rounded to
the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard errors clustered at the
institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3)
StickerTuition
it
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
0.264 0.546
∗∗
0.603
∗∗
[0.28] [0.17] [0.17]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
0.170
∗∗
-0.173 0.185
∗∗
[0.04] [0.11] [0.04]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
0.384
∗∗
0.506
∗∗
0.541
[0.15] [0.16] [0.32]
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
×Private
i
0.304
∗∗
[0.11]
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
×FourYear
i
-0.321
∗∗
[0.11]
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
×Tuition04
i
0.022
∗∗
[0.01]
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
×EFC04
i
-0.015
[0.01]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
×Private
i
0.061
[0.04]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
×FourYear
i
-0.047
[0.04]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
×Tuition04
i
0.009
∗∗
[0.00]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
×EFC04
i
0.000
[0.00]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
×Private
i
-0.040
[0.13]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
×FourYear
i
0.041
[0.14]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
×Tuition04
i
-0.010
[0.01]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
×EFC04
i
-0.007
[0.02]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
0.38 0.38 0.38
N Obs 10570 10570 10570
N Inst 1060 1060 1060
46
Table 9: Years of Federal Loan, Pell Grant, and Tuition increases for For-Profit and Not-for-Profit
institutions These tables regress annual changes in federal subsidized and unsubsidized loans, Pell
Grants, and sticker price tuition against year dummies. The omitted dummy is for the year 2006.
The Year = 2008,09,10 is a dummy varaible corresponding to those years, which is when the federal
aid cap changes take effect. Standard errors clustered at the institution level reported in brackets.
Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
For-Profits
PellGrants
it
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
StickerTuition
it
Year = 2002 178
∗∗
[14] -74
∗∗
[19] -246
∗∗
[29] 25 [49]
Year = 2003 110
∗∗
[13] -64
∗∗
[17] -194
∗∗
[27] 226
∗∗
[46]
Year = 2004 -28
∗∗
[12] -84
∗∗
[17] -210
∗∗
[26] 36 [25]
Year = 2005 -112
∗∗
[14] -115
∗∗
[18] -252
∗∗
[27] 86
∗∗
[25]
Year = 2007 -35
∗∗
[14] -50
∗∗
[18] -317
∗∗
[27] 83
∗∗
[25]
Year = 2008 89
∗∗
[14] 460
∗∗
[20] -117
∗∗
[27] 205
∗∗
[27]
Year = 2009 252
∗∗
[14] -53
∗∗
[18] 670
∗∗
[29] 269
∗∗
[29]
Year = 2010 728
∗∗
[17] -264
∗∗
[18] -485
∗∗
[27] 269
∗∗
[29]
Year = 2011 106
∗∗
[16] -215
∗∗
[18] -576
∗∗
[28] 88
∗∗
[28]
Year = 2012 -485
∗∗
[18] -249
∗∗
[19] -374
∗∗
[30] -102
∗∗
[30]
Constant 85
∗∗
[8] 164
∗∗
[10] 371
∗∗
[15] 487
∗∗
[15]
PellGrants
it
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
StickerTuition
it
Year = 2008,09,10 386
∗∗
[8] 148
∗∗
[9] 272
∗∗
[13] 212
∗∗
[16]
Constant 50
∗∗
[2] 67
∗∗
[2] 126
∗∗
[4] 523
∗∗
[5]
Inst FE? Yes Yes Yes Yes
N Obs 18750 16980 16760 16880
N Inst 2050 1910 1900 2090
Not-for-Profits
PellGrants
it
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
StickerTuition
it
Year = 2002 -106
∗∗
[7] -260
∗∗
[9] -513
∗∗
[12] -164
∗∗
[12]
Year = 2003 -157
∗∗
[7] -165
∗∗
[9] -456
∗∗
[12] -38
∗∗
[13]
Year = 2004 -229
∗∗
[7] -174
∗∗
[9] -477
∗∗
[12] 60
∗∗
[14]
Year = 2005 -252
∗∗
[7] -201
∗∗
[9] -483
∗∗
[12] 33
∗∗
[13]
Year = 2007 -262
∗∗
[7] -257
∗∗
[9] -588
∗∗
[12] 6 [12]
Year = 2008 -161
∗∗
[7] -22
∗∗
[10] -445
∗∗
[13] 46
∗∗
[12]
Year = 2009 -76
∗∗
[7] -223
∗∗
[9] 10 [16] 79
∗∗
[12]
Year = 2010 294
∗∗
[9] -186
∗∗
[9] -452
∗∗
[14] 54
∗∗
[13]
Year = 2011 -32
∗∗
[8] -237
∗∗
[10] -688
∗∗
[14] 36
∗∗
[13]
Year = 2012 -315
∗∗
[8] -241
∗∗
[9] -560
∗∗
[13] 90
∗∗
[12]
Constant 260
∗∗
[5] 292
∗∗
[5] 630
∗∗
[7] 618
∗∗
[7]
PellGrants
it
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
StickerTuition
it
Year = 2008,09,10 159
∗∗
[4] 16
∗∗
[4] 94
∗∗
[7] 54
∗∗
[7]
Constant 118
∗∗
[1] 134
∗∗
[1] 241
∗∗
[2] 623
∗∗
[2]
Inst FE? Yes Yes Yes Yes
N Obs 39420 38390 37830 37850
N Inst 3550 3440 3420 3630
47
Appendix
A Proof of model propositions
Proof of Proposition 1 Letting λ be the Lagrange multiplier on the capacity constraint, the first order conditions are:
γN
1
qδD
q,U
+ (1 γ)N
1
D
q,U
(1 γ)(t
q,U
c)δD
q,U
λδD
q,U
= 0 (15)
γN
1
q(δ + ω)D
q,C
+ (1 γ)N
1
D
q,C
(1 γ)(t
q,C
c)(δ + ω)D
q,C
λ(δ + ω)D
q,C
= 0 (16)
for q = q
H
, q
L
, where we have used the observation that
D
q,U
t
q,U
= δD
q,U
and
D
q,C
t
q,C
= (δ + ω)D
q,C
. When λ > 0 (i.e. the
constraint binds) this gives us the solutions above.
Proof of Proposition 2 We first note that:
t(q, n)
B
=
1
1 γ
λ
B
(17)
for q = q
H
, q
L
and n = n
U
, n
C
. We can solve implicitly for λ
B
by taking the derivative of the constraint D
U
+ D
C
= N
with respect to B.
D
U
B
+
D
C
B
= 0. (18)
Notice that:
D
U
B
=
δD
U
1 γ
∂λ
B
(19)
D
C
B
=
(δ + ω)D
C
1 γ
∂λ
B
+ ωD
C
(20)
This gives us:
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
1 γ
∂λ
G
= ωD
C
(21)
λ
B
=
(1 γ)D
C
ω
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
(22)
λ
B
=
(1 γ)D
C
ω
δN + D
C
ω
(23)
Thus we have that:
t(q, n)
B
=
D
C
ω
δN + D
C
ω
> 0 (24)
Proof of Proposition 3 We use the expression for
t(q,n)
B
from above to write that:
s
t
B
=
(δN + D
C
ω)ω
D
C
s
D
C
ωω
D
C
s
(δN + D
C
ω)
2
(25)
=
δNω
(δN + D
C
ω)
2
D
C
s
(26)
48
Thus, showing the first comparative static is equivalent to showing that
D
C
s
> 0. We compute:
D
U
s
= q
D
L,U
s
+ (1 q)
D
H,U
s
(27)
= q
D
L,U
1 s
qδD
L,U
t
L,U
s
(1 q)
D
H,U
1 s
(1 q)δD
H,U
t
H,U
s
(28)
=
D
U
1 s
δD
U
1 γ
∂λ
s
(29)
and likewise:
D
C
s
=
D
C
s
(δ + ω)D
C
1 γ
∂λ
s
(30)
Then we solve for λ
s
by again taking derivatives of the constraint:
D
U
s
+
D
C
s
= 0 (31)
D
U
1 s
+
D
C
s
=
1
1 γ
∂λ
s
h
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
i
(32)
λ
s
=
(1 γ)(D
U
/s D
U
/(1 s))
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
(33)
λ
s
=
(1 γ)(D
C
N)
s(1 s)
δN + ωD
C
(34)
Thus:
D
C
s
> 0
1
s
>
(δ + ω)
1 γ
(1 γ)(D
C
N)
s(1 s)(δN + ωD
C
)
(35)
1 s >
(δ + ω)(D
L
N)
δN + ωD
L
(36)
Since the RHS is negative, this inequality is always true.
Sensitivity of tuition response to for-profit motive Here we show that
∂γ
t
B
< 0
D
H,C
D
C
<
δD
H,U
+ (δ + ω)D
H,C
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
(37)
We use the expression for
t(q,n)
B
from above to write that:
∂γ
t
B
=
δNω
(δN + D
C
ω)
2
D
C
∂γ
(38)
and thus that we want to show that:
D
C
∂γ
< 0. We compute the derivatives of the demand function with respect to
γ as follows:
D
q,U
∂γ
= δD
q,U
q + λ
(1 γ)
2
+
1
1 γ
∂λ
∂γ
(39)
D
q,C
∂γ
= (δ + ω)D
q,C
q + λ
(1 γ)
2
+
1
1 γ
∂λ
∂γ
(40)
49
We use these to solve for λ
γ
:
D
H,U
∂γ
+
D
L,U
∂γ
+
D
H,C
∂γ
+
D
H,C
∂γ
= 0
δ(D
H,U
(q
H
+ λ) + D
L,U
(q
L
+ λ)) + (δ + ω)(D
H,C
(q
H
+ λ) + D
L,C
(q
L
+ λ))
(1 γ)
2
=
∂λ
∂γ
1
1 γ
h
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
i
λ
γ
=
δ(D
H,U
(q
H
+ λ) + D
L,U
(q
L
+ λ)) + (δ + ω)(D
H,C
(q
H
+ λ) + D
L,C
(q
L
+ λ))
(1 γ)
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
λ
γ
=
δD
H,U
+ (δ + ω)D
H,C
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
q
H
+ λ
1 λ
+
δD
L,U
+ (δ + ω)D
L,C
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
q
L
+ λ
1 λ
(41)
Thus:
D
C
∂γ
= (δ + ω)
D
C
1
1 γ
∂λ
∂γ
D
H,C
q
H
+ λ
(1 γ)
2
D
L,C
q
L
+ λ
(1 γ)
2
(42)
D
C
∂γ
< 0 λ
γ
>
D
H,C
D
C
q
H
+ λ
1 γ
+
D
L,C
D
C
q
L
+ λ
1 γ
(43)
δD
H,U
+ (δ + ω)D
H,C
δD
U
+ (δ + ω)D
C
>
D
H,C
D
C
(44)
where the final implication follows from the fact that the left and right sides are both weighted sums of
q
H
+λ
1γ
and
q
L
+λ
1γ
where the weights sum to 1, and q
H
> q
L
.
B Overview of the postsecondary education industry
This Appendix provides basic facts about the postsecondary education industry. As discussed above, average un-
dergraduate per student tuition nearly doubled between 2001 and 2012, from about $6,950 to more than $10,000 in 2012
dollars (Figure 1), corresponding to an average real rate increase of 3.5% per year.
These overall trends in college tuition mask significant variation within the postsecondary education sector. Tuition
at postsecondary educational institutions varies widely depending on the type of degree the institution offers (four-year
bachelor’s degrees, two-year associate’s degrees, or certificates generally requiring less than two years of full time study)
and by the type of governance it operates under (for example, non-profit or for-profit).
In the 2011-2012 school year, there were 10.7 million undergraduate students enrolled at four-year institutions, and
7.5 million students enrolled at two-year institutions (see Figure 8). Four-year institutions also enrolled an additional 2.8
million graduate students, though we focus mainly on undergraduate loan amounts and tuition in this paper. Four-year
institutions, which include public state universities (60% of enrollment in 2012), private non-profit research universities
and liberal arts colleges (29%), and private for-profit institutions (11%), rely on a combination of revenue sources, from
government appropriations to tuition revenue to other revenue (mostly private endowments and gifts). The two-year
sector is almost entirely dominated by public two-year colleges, also known as community colleges, which enroll about
95% of all two-year students. Tuition at these colleges is low, averaging just $2,600 in 2012. Most of the revenue (70%) of
these colleges instead comes from government sources.
Finally, in addition to the 20.4 million students enrolled at degree-granting institutions (two-year and four-year
institutions) in 2012, another 572,000 were enrolled at Title IV “less-than-two-year” institutions. These institutions are
mostly vocational schools in fields such as technology, business, cosmetology, hair styling, photography, and fashion.
In contrast to the degree-granting institutions, the majority of these institutions are private for-profit institutions and
tuition revenue makes up the majority of their funding.
The above numbers only cover Title IV institutions, but many for-profit institutions exist that are not Title IV-
eligible.
22
Data on these institutions is hard to find since they are not tracked by the US Department of Education, but
22
All public institutions are eligible for Title IV. Other institutions must meet certain qualifications such as being li-
censed, accredited from a Nationally Recognized Accrediting Agency (NRAA), and meeting standards of administrative
50
Cellini and Goldin (2014) construct a dataset using administrative data from five states, and show that, after controlling
for observables, tuition at Title-IV-eligible for-profit institutions are 75% higher than comparable non-Title-IV-eligible
for-profit institutions.
C Additional earnings calls transcripts
In this Section we provide additional passages taken from earnings calls of the Apollo Group discussing the changes
in federal student aid maximums.
<Q - Mark Marostica>: My question first relates to Brian’s comment on the national pricing strategy, and
I was wondering if you can give us some more specifics around that and whether or not you are actually
planning to lower prices as part of that.
<A - Brian Mueller>: It is something that we are considering. I have talked about it the last couple
of conferences we’ve attended. We have a very unique opportunity in July. Loan limits go up for first
and second level students, which is fairly long overdue. By the time we get to July I am estimating that
upwards of 70% of all students who are studying at the University of Phoenix at the level one and level
two at those levels will be at Axia College at Axia College tuition rates. So there will be some room for
us to raise tuition there from maybe 265 to 295 and from 285 to maybe 310, without putting a burden on
students from a standpoint of out-of-pocket expense. At the graduate level there is a lot of room. We are
actually quite a bit under the competition in our graduate programs, and there is a lot of room from a Title
IV standpoint so that, again, we wouldnt put a burden on students from an out-of-pocket expense.
Source: Apollo Education Group, 2006:Q4 Earnings Call, accessed from Bloomberg LP Transcripts.
<Q - Mark Hughes>: And then any early view on whether Axia, with the price increase there affecting
start levels in May?
<A - Brian Mueller> Whether it’s affecting start levels in May?
<Q - Mark Hughes>: Right. 10% increase in tuition. Is anybody balking at that, or trends steady?
<A - Brian Mueller>: No, thank you for asking that. No, because loan limits are raised on July 1, for level
1 and 2 students. And so students know as they go in if they’re going to have enough title IV dollars to
cover the cost of their tuition, so, no, it’s not impacting new student starts.
Source: Apollo Education Group, 2007:Q2 Earnings Call, accessed from Bloomberg LP Transcripts.
<Q - Brandon Dobell>: One final one. Maybe as you think about discounting, at least the philosophy
around affordability, pricing, discounting across the different brands or different programs, maybe, Brian,
if you could speak to, has there been any change in terms of how you guys think about that? Do you think
that discounting generates the wrong type of student or the right type of student, or how flexible do you
think it will be going forward in terms of how you think about affordability issues?
<A - Brian Mueller>: We’re not changing our thinking about that. It’s really clear what’s going on in
the country economically, with the middle class getting squeezed. People don’t have disposable income
to spend for private school education but they understand its impact on their long-term career so they’re
willing to borrow the money at really good rates from a Title IV standpoint. And so if you can build your
operations to the point that you can be profitable and keep those tuition rates inside Title IV loan limits
you’re going to do positive things with regards to retention, which will offset maybe the 4 to 6% increases
that we would have gotten in the past.
Source: Apollo Education Group, 2007:Q2 Earnings Call, accessed from Bloomberg LP Transcripts.
D Stock market event study analysis
Here we discuss stock market responses of publicly traded for-profit institutions to the three legislative changes
discussed in Section 3. Table A1 reports event studies for abnormal returns over 3-day windows surrounding the passage
of the three legislative changes to the HEA. Fourteen for-profit education companies were publicly traded around at least
one of these legislative changes (and eight across all changes), including the Apollo Education Group among others. The
capacity and financial responsibility (e.g., default rates of graduates in excess of 25% for three consecutive years, or a
one-year default rate in excess of 40%, are grounds for losing Title IV status).
51
cumulative abnormal returns are computed as each stock’s excess return to the CRSP index returns, summed over the
3-day event window. We then calculate the (market cap) weighted and unweighted average of the cumulative abnormal
returns of the eight publicly traded for-profit institutions to the index.
In the top panel of Table A1, we see that average 3-day cumulative abnormal returns around the 2006 re-authorization
of HEA, which increased the subsidized loan limits for freshman and sophomores, were 3.64% and 2.9% under the value-
and equally-weighted market benchmarks, respectively. The abnormal returns are statistically significant and econom-
ically large. As shown in the middle panel, three-day cumulative abnormal returns surrounding the 2007 legislative
passage that increased Pell Grant amounts were 2.17% and 2.22%, respectively. Finally, we consider two separate event
windows for the passing of the Ensuring Equal Access to Student Loans Act of 2008 which increased unsubsidized
borrowing amounts.
23
Depending on the exact window used, abnormal returns on the for-profit institution portfolio
ranged between 4.8% and 3.3%.
In sum, we find evidence that the passage of three pieces of legislation were associated with sizable abnormal stock
market responses for the portfolio of publicly traded for-profit institutions. The nearly 10% abnormal return is consistent
with the fact that students at for-profit institutions rely heavily on federal student aid to fund their education. In addition,
anecdotal evidence also supports the view that changes in Title-IV programs boosted tuition at these institutions.
Table A1: Stock Market Reactions to Changes in Federal Aid Policy This table reports 3-day cu-
mulative abnormal returns for a portfolio of 14 publicly traded for-profit universities surrounding
dates of legislative passage to changes in Federal Aid Policy. Returns are computed in excess of the
CRSP index on a value-weighted and equal-weighted basis.
Event Date Mkt Weights Policy Event Window Mean Cum.
Abnormal
Ret.
Z score
Congress reauthorized the
Higher Education Act
2/1/2006 v Sub./Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 3.64% (3.216)
e Sub./Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 2.90% (2.545)
College Cost Reduction
and Access Act Passes
Congress
9/7/2007 v Pell Grants (-1,+1) 2.17% (2.204)
e Pell Grants (-1,+1) 2.22% (2.242)
Ensuring Equal Access to
Student Loans Act of 2008
is passed by the Senate
4/30/2008 v Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 4.86% (2.570)
e Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 4.80% (2.480)
Ensuring Equal Access to
Student Loans Act of 2008
is passed by Congress
5/1/2008 v Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 3.30% (1.752)
e Unsub. Loans (-1,+1) 3.62% (1.933)
E Data detail
This Appendix complements Section 4 in providing a more detailed data description. The data used in the empirical
analysis throughout this paper comes from three sources: IPEDS, Title IV, and NPSAS. We provide institutional details
on each. We then describe in detail the variables we constructed using the data from each of these sources.
Survey Data: The IPEDS survey covers seven areas: institutional characteristics, institutional prices, enrollment,
student financial aid, degrees and certificates conferred, student retention and graduation rates, and institutional hu-
23
On April 30, 2008 the Senate passed the Act, after already having received approval by the House. However, the
Senate’s approving vote included some changes that had to be subsequently ratified by the House. Thus, the bill essen-
tially passed on April 30, 2008, but the changes made by the Senate were not voted on, and subsequently passed by the
House, until May 1, 2008. For completeness, we estimate three-day abnormal returns around both event dates, though
the two event window obviously overlap on one day.
52
man resources and finances. While IPEDS is the most comprehensive dataset on postsecondary education available,
because it is based on surveys of administrators, it is not always sufficiently detailed or reliable for our purposes. For
measures of federal aid at the institutional level, we found that the figures contained in the IPEDS ”Student Financial
Aid” survey did not meet our needs for a couple reasons. First, the survey restricts the universe to aid amounts for
”full-time first-time degree-seeking undergraduates,” which is not our student population of interest; second, in part
because of this restriction, the survey has been labeled as the most burdensome of surveys (Government Accountability
Office (2010)); and third, until recently, the survey did not distinguish between federal loans and other loans, and still
does not distinguish between subsidized and unsubsidized loans, which makes our identification more difficult.
Title IV data serve as our primary data source for measuring federal loans and pell grants at the institution level.
While we considered also using IPEDS to obtain these measures, we ultimately found a number of reasons to look to the
Title IV data. One of the reasons is that the IPEDS measures of financial aid are contained in the “Student Financial Aid”
survey, which is considered by most educational administrators to be the most burdensome of the IPEDS surveys (Gov-
ernment Accountability Office (2010)). This is likely because it requires administrators to estimate the total amount of
aid and number of recipients within a specific IPEDS-defined universe of students, ‘’full-time first-time degree-seeking
undergraduates. Restricting to this universe may be difficult for some institutions depending on what data sources
they pull from to complete the IPEDS surveys. Thus, these data are less reliable than those obtained from the less-
burdensome collection of published tuition levels and enrollment numbers. Second, this universe is not necessarily
representative of the entire undergraduate body. Third, until recently, IPEDS did not distinguish between federal loans
and other loans, and still does not distinguish between subsidized and unsubsidized loans, which makes our identifica-
tion more difficult. We describe the benefits of the Title IV data relative to the IPEDS data in Section 4 in the main body
of the text.
Sample: Our sample begins in the 2000-2001 school year, the first year that the tuition sticker price survey from
IPEDS more or less takes the current form. We end our sample in 2011-2012, since in 2012-2013, changes to graduate
financial aid occur that may interfere with our identification. IPEDS and NPSAS data are reported at institution level
(UNITID), while Title IV is reported at the OPEID level. This is because there may be multiple UNITIDs associated to
one OPEID, as branches (UNITID) of the same institution are sometimes surveyed separately. Our regressions are done
at the OPEID level, where when we are using averages of variables in IPEDS, we take enrollment-weighted averages of
the UNITIDs.
Sticker-Price Tuition: Our main dependent variable is yearly changes in the sticker-price tuition at the institutional
level. This data comes from the IPEDS Student Charges survey. For full academic-year programs, we use the sum of the
out-of-state average tuition for full-time undergraduates and the out-of-state required fees for full-time undergraduates.
For other programs, we use the published tuition and fees for the entire program. For public universitites we use out-
of-state tuition rather than average tuition to abstract from variation driven by changing fractions of in-state versus
out-of-state students. We generally find that the in-state and out-of-state differences are highly correlated.
Enrollment: Enrollment can be measured both as headcount and full-time equivalent students. In general, we use
an IPEDS formula to calculate a full-time-equivalent (FTE) enrollment measure. In certain cases though, we use total
headcounts from the IPEDS enrollment survey, which are available by student level and attendance status.
Federal Loan and Grant Usage: For federal loan and grant totals, we rely on Title IV administrative data rather than
the student financial aid survey from IPEDS, which appears to be somewhat unreliable as it is survey based. Title IV data
contains the number of recipients, and total dollar amount of loans originated or grants disbursed for each institution
and each of subsidized loans, unsubsidized loans, and Pell Grants. We only consider undergraduate policy changes and
tuition in this paper, so we would want these amounts to be for undergraduates only. However, Title IV data does not
break out undergraduate and graduate loans separately until 2011. Pell Grants are only available to undergraduates,
so are not affected. Since imputation of an undergraduate measure requires making several assumptions, our preferred
measure of loan and grant usage at an institution is just the total dollar amount scaled by the FTE count of the university.
We also report results for robustness when we scale the total dollar amount by the total enrollment count. Finally, also
for robustness, we make an attempt to impute an undergraduate measure as follows: Since the maximum subsidized
loan amount changes only for undergraduates in our sample, we assume a constant average graduate loan amount
over time,
¯
g
i
conditional on borrowing. In addition, we assume that the fraction of all subsidized loan borrowers at an
institution who are graduate students also does not change, γ
i
. To calculate
¯
g
i
and γ
i
, we take the averages of the 2011
53
and 2012 values.
24
For prior years, given the total subsidized loan amount S
it
, we calculate the undergraduate dollar
amount borrowed as: S
it
γ
i
¯
g
i
. We then scale this measure by total undergraduate enrollment.
Exposures: We calculate exposures using confidential NPSAS data as described in Section 4.3.
Net Tuition and Institutional Grants: Our institutional grant data comes from the IPEDS Finance Survey, which
records as an expenditure item total grant dollars spent on scholarships and fellowships. We scale this measure by the
FTE enrollment. We compute net tuition by subtracting institutional grants per FTE from sticker price.
Financing Controls: We follow the Delta Cost Project data in separating revenue data into a few main parts. The
first is net tuition revenue, as described above. The next is federal funding, excluding Pell Grants. The third is state (and
local) funding through appropriations and contracts. The fourth is private funding (from donations, or endowment
investment income), and the fifth is revenue from auxiliary operations (e.g. hospitals, dormitories). We use changes in
these amounts, scaled by FTE enrollment, as controls in our regressions.
Other Controls: Average EFC comes from NPSAS data, and the admission rate comes from IPEDS.
F Additional robustness tests
Using 2008 NPSAS exposures: In the baseline specification we measure institution exposures using the 2004
NPSAS wave, the closest available wave that still predates the changes in loan (and most of the grant) maximums.
Despite the results in Table 3, one may worry about the time gap between when the exposures are computed and when
the policy changes take place. In Table A2 we re-estimate the baseline specification using exposures computed from
2008 NPSAS for robustness. Aid sensitivities to changes in the institution-specific program aid maximums as of 2008
maximums (columns 1-3) are very similar to the 2004 ones, with the exception of the subsidized loan sensitivity response
to the subsidized loan maximums, which increases to 1.25 from .7 in Table 3. Subsidized loan maximums are increased in
2008, so that the 2008 subsidized loan exposure is measured at the post-policy maximum amounts. To the extent that not
all students fully expanded their borrowing (as suggested by comparing the 2004-08 subsidized exposures in Table 2 and
the loading in Table 3), the sensitivity of 2008 to 2004 subsidized exposures drops, resulting in a higher point estimate
in column 3. Sticker tuition displays a very similar sensitivity to the institution-level change in program maximums
(compare columns 4 in Tables 3 and A2), although the point estimate on Pell Grants is less precisely estimated (t-stat =
1.66). In Table A3, we repeat the IV estimates of Table ?? using exposures computed as of 2008 NPSAS and obtain very
similar results, except for a lower sensitivity of sticker tuition to subsidized loans owing to the overstated pre-policy
exposure discussed above.
Dependent variables in logarithms: Because changes in federal aid policies affected dollar levels, rather than
percentage changes, of the program maximums, the dependent variables in our baseline specification are expressed
in dollar changes. In Table A4 we re-estimate the specification with the dependent variable expressed in logarithmic
changes. While this specification does not directly match the policy change, it can be informative about the magnitude
of percentage effects of the changes in program caps. Starting with the percentage change response of aid levels, Pell
amounts (column 1) now load with an incorrect (negative) sign on changes in Pell caps.
25
Subsidized and unsubsidized
loans (columns 2 and 3) load positively on changes in their respective caps and negatively on the Pell Grant caps suggest-
ing substitution from loans to grants, as in the baseline specification in dollar changes. Finally, in terms of percentage
changes in tuition, a $100 increase in the program caps resulted in .4%, .2% and .1% (statistically significant) increases,
respectively, for Pell Grants, subsidized, and unsubsidized loans.
24
We drop institutions from our sample where the 2011 and 2012 values differ significantly.
25
This may owe to the percentage-change specification along with the fact that, because of the program design, Pell
Grant exposures include all recipients receiving a positive, rather than only those at the program maximums as it is the
case for subsidized and unsubsidized loans.
54
Table A2: Baseline regression specification using 2008 NPSAS exposures This table replicates
Table 3 using NPSAS aid exposures as of 2008 as opposed to 2004 ones. See notes to Table 3 for
more details. Sample sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure
policies. Standard errors clustered at the institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p <
0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
SubLoans
it
UnsubLoans
it
PellGrants
it
StickerTuition
it
StickerTuition
it
SubLoanExp08
i
× SLCap
t
1.223
∗∗
0.106 0.108 0.609
∗∗
[0.11] [0.16] [0.08] [0.23]
UnsubLoanExp08
i
× USLCap
t
0.030 0.650
∗∗
-0.057
∗∗
0.233
∗∗
[0.02] [0.04] [0.01] [0.04]
PellGrantExp08
i
× PGCap
t
-0.346
∗∗
-0.466
∗∗
0.997
∗∗
0.283
[0.08] [0.15] [0.09] [0.17]
SubLoans
it
0.891
∗∗
[0.35]
UnsubLoans
it
0.243
∗∗
[0.10]
PellGrants
it
0.527
∗∗
[0.18]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
0.08 0.23 0.48 0.39 -0.45
N Obs 13610 13540 14000 14500 9320
N Inst 1340 1350 1410 1420 970
Table A3: IV regression specification using 2008 NPSAS exposures This table replicates Table ??
using NPSAS aid exposures as of 2008 as opposed to 2004 ones. See notes to Table ?? for more
details. Sample sizes are rounded to the nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure poli-
cies. Standard errors clustered at the institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2)
StickerTuition
it
PellGrants
it
0.270
0.559
∗∗
[0.16] [0.18]
SubLoans
it
0.502
∗∗
[0.22]
UnsubLoans
it
0.352
∗∗
[0.07]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes
N Obs 13110 13110
N Inst 1340 1340
55
Figure 8: Enrollments, Sticker Tuition and Revenue by Program Type These figures plot total
enrollment, average sticker price, and average revenues per student for institutions, depending on
the type of program offered in the 2011-2012 school year. Source: IPEDS.
(a) Total undergraduate enrollment by institution pro-
gram type (millions)
0 2 4 6 8 10
Millions
4-Year 2-Year Less-than-2-Year
(b) Average sticker price by institution program type
0 5,000 10,000 15,000
Dollars
4-Year 2-Year Less-than-2-Year
(c) Average per-student revenues by institution program
type
0 10,000 20,000 30,000
Dollars
4-Year 2-Year Less-than-2-Year
Net Tuition Gov. Appropriations and Contracts
Other
56
Table A4: Baseline regression specification with dependent variables in logarithmic changes
This table replicates Table 3, but uses percentage changes in the dependent variables rather than
changes in absolute terms. See notes to Table 3 for more details. Sample sizes are rounded to the
nearest 10 in compliance with NPSAS nondisclosure policies. Standard errors clustered at the
institution level reported in brackets. Significance:
p < 0.1,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗
p < 0.01.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
logPellGrants
it
logSubLoans
it
logUnsubLoans
it
logStickerTuition
it
SubLoanExp
i
× SLCap
t
0.009
0.009
0.000 0.002
[0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00]
UnsubLoanExp
i
× USLCap
t
-0.003
∗∗
0.001 0.014
∗∗
0.001
∗∗
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
PellGrantExp
i
× PGCap
t
-0.016
∗∗
-0.017
∗∗
-0.026
∗∗
0.004
∗∗
[0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00]
Inst&Year FE? Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adj R
2
0.49 0.13 0.19 0.04
N Obs 10040 9740 9730 10480
N Inst 1040 990 990 1060
57